Federal Reserve Fines Six Major Banking Organisations $1.8 billion For Rigging FX Markets

The Federal Reserve on Wednesday announced it will impose fines totaling more than $1.8 billion against six major banking organizations for their unsafe and unsound practices in the foreign exchange (FX) markets. The fines, among the largest ever assessed by the Federal Reserve, include: $342 million each for UBS AG, Barclays Bank PLC, Citigroup Inc., and JPMorgan Chase & Co.; $274 million for Royal Bank of Scotland PLC (RBS); and $205 million for Bank of America Corporation. The Federal Reserve also issued cease and desist orders requiring the firms to improve their policies and procedures for oversight and controls over activities in the wholesale FX and similar types of markets.

The Federal Reserve is requiring the firms to correct deficiencies in their oversight and internal controls over traders who buy and sell U.S. dollars and foreign currencies for the organizations’ own accounts and for customers. As a result of these deficient policies and procedures, the organizations engaged in unsafe and unsound conduct by failing to detect and address improper actions by their traders. These actions included the disclosure in electronic chatrooms of confidential customer information to traders at other organizations. Five of the banks failed to detect and address illegal agreements among traders to manipulate benchmark currency prices. Bank of America failed to detect and address conduct by traders who discussed the possibility of entering into similar agreements to manipulate prices. In addition, the Federal Reserve found UBS, Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, and Barclays engaged in unsafe and unsound conduct in FX sales, including conduct relating to how the organizations disclosed to customers the methods for determining price quotes.

The Federal Reserve is requiring the six organizations to improve their senior management oversight, internal controls, risk management, and internal audit policies and procedures for their FX activities and for similar kinds of trading activities and is requiring four of the organizations to improve controls over their sales practices. The Federal Reserve is also requiring all six organizations to cooperate in its investigation of the individuals involved in the conduct underlying these enforcement actions and is prohibiting the organizations from re-employing or otherwise engaging individuals who were involved in unsafe and unsound conduct.

The Federal Reserve is taking action against UBS, Barclays, Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, and RBS concurrently with the Department of Justice’s criminal charges against these five organizations related to misconduct in the FX markets. Bank of America was not part of the actions taken by the Department of Justice and has not been charged by the Department of Justice in this matter.

The Connecticut Department of Banking has joined the cease and desist provisions of the Federal Reserve’s action against UBS, which has a branch located in Stamford, Connecticut. The New York Department of Financial Services has taken a separate action against Barclays and its New York branch based on FX-related conduct.

Treasury Consults on Proposed Financial Institutions Supervisory Levies for 2015-16

The financial institutions supervisory levies are set to recover the operational costs of APRA and other specific costs incurred by certain Commonwealth agencies and departments, including the Australian Securities and Investments Commission, the Australian Taxation Office, and the Department of Human Services.

By way of background, in December 2002, the Government adopted a formal cost recovery policy to improve the consistency, transparency and accountability of cost recovered activities and promote the efficient allocation of resources. Cost recovery involves government entities charging individuals or non-government organisations some or all of the efficient costs of a specific government activity.

On 16 April 2014, Treasury released a paper responding to the submissions received on the methodology review and its conclusions informed last year’s discussion paper on the levies to be imposed in 2014-15. In the 2014-15 discussion paper, industry was further asked to provide Government with their views in relation to whether:  The 2014-15 levies should be calculated in the same way as the 2013-14 levies (Option 1), or; For the 2014-15 levies, the costs of all activities, except for APRA’s prudential supervision, should be allocated to the unrestricted levy component with the maximum cap for superannuation funds lowered to reflect the cost of SuperStream being met from the unrestricted component, and Pooled Superannuation Trusts to be levied at a lower rate to reflect the lower intensity of regulation required (Option 2).

Industry was also asked to provide Government with their views on whether the SuperStream levy payable should continue to be calculated on a net assets basis or with reference to the number of superannuation fund members. Following industry consultation, the Government elected to determine the levies payable in 2014-15 using the methodology outlined in Option 2. This methodology will be used to determine the levies payable in 2015-16.

APRA’s net funding requirements under the levies for 2015-16 is $125.1 million, a $2.7 million (2.2 per cent) increase relative to budget for 2014-15. $6.6 million of these costs will be met through other sources of APRA revenue (referred to as net cost offsets) and Government appropriations, including a special levy for the National Claims and Policies Database (NCPD). Taking into account $1.0 million in projected over-collected 2014-15 levies to be returned to industry, APRA’s underlying net levies funding requirement for 2015-16 is $117.5 million, an increase of $0.6 million (0.5 per cent) relative to budget for 2014-15.

A component of the levies is collected to partially offset the expenses of ASIC in relation to consumer protection, financial literacy, regulatory and enforcement activities relating to the products and services of APRA regulated institutions as well as the operation of the Superannuation Complaints Tribunal (SCT). In addition, the levies are used to offset the cost of a number of Government initiatives including the over the counter (OTC) derivatives market supervision reforms and ASIC’s MoneySmart programmes. $28.2 million will be recovered for ASIC through the levies in 2015-16.

Funding from the levies collected from the superannuation industry includes a component to cover the expenses of the ATO in administering the Superannuation Lost Member Register (LMR) and Unclaimed Superannuation Money (USM) frameworks. The estimated total cost to the ATO of undertaking these functions in 2014-15 is $18.3 million, of which $7.1 million was recovered through the levies. In 2015-16, it is estimated that the total cost to the ATO in undertaking these functions will be $17.9 million with the full amount to be recovered through the levies in line with the requirements of the Government’s CRGs.

The Department of Human Services administers the early release of superannuation benefits on compassionate grounds. The compassionate grounds enable the Regulator (the Chief Executive of Medicare) to consider the early release of a person’s preserved superannuation in specified circumstances. In 2013-14, the Early Release of Superannuation Benefits programme received 19,286 applications. This was a 7 per cent increase compared with the previous year. In 2014-15, the Early Release of Superannuation Benefits programme is forecast to receive approximately 20,500 applications. This will represent an approximate increase in volume of 6.3 per cent compared with the previous year.
The programme is expected to cost the Government $4.7 million in 2015-16 and, in line with the CRGs, this amount will be recovered in full through the levies.

Announced as part of the former Government’s Stronger Super reforms, SuperStream is a collection of measures that are designed to deliver greater efficiency in back-office processing across the superannuation industry. Superannuation funds will benefit from standardised and simplified data and payment administration processes when dealing with employers and other funds and from easier matching and consolidation of superannuation accounts. The costs associated with the implementation of the SuperStream measures are to be collected as part of the levies on superannuation funds. The levies will recover the full cost of the implementation of the SuperStream reforms and are to be imposed as a temporary levy on APRA-regulated superannuation entities from 2012-13 to 2017-18 inclusive. The levy payable is subject to the Minister’s determination. The costs associated with the implementation of the SuperStream reforms are estimated to be $61.8 million in 2015-16, $35.5 million in 2016-17, and $32.0 million in 2017-18.

The Treasury paper, prepared in conjunction with the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA), seeks submissions on the proposed financial institutions supervisory levies that will apply for the 2015-16 financial year. Closing date for submissions: Wednesday, 10 June 2015

 

 

 

Average Super Fund Return Was 13% In 2014 – APRA

APRA just released their Superannuation Fund-level Profiles and Financial Performance (interim edition). Superannuation funds included in this publication represent the vast majority of superannuation assets regulated by APRA. It contains data for all APRA-regulated superannuation funds with more than four members. Pooled superannuation trusts (PSTs) have been excluded from the publication publications as their assets are captured in other superannuation funds. Exempt public sector superannuation schemes (EPSSS) have also been excluded.

The fund by fund data tells an interesting story. The average across retail, corporate, public sector and industry funds was 13%. This is calculated by taking the returns and costs at a fund level to create a net fund return. Individual members within a fund will see different true returns, based on the options they choose and other elements. However, it gets interesting if we look across the nearly 2oo funds.  Several funds are returning below 5%, and a few above 14%.

SuperReturnsAll2014What is even more interesting is that the size of the fund is not a good predictor of performance. We can see this by mapping returns to number of members.  The biggest fund returned under 10%, the next two between 12% and 14%. But we see some smaller funds out performing, and others languishing. That said, one year’s performance is not necessarily a good indicator of longer term performance anyhow.

MemberMapAll2014What is clear, is that Industry Funds, on average, still return more than retail funds. Corporate (private) funds do even better.

AveragePerSuper2014So, we can then look across each of the main types of fund. First, retail. There are about 100 retail funds. The average returns varies widely. Not all individual funds are listed here, but the graph includes all data points.

RetailFundsReturns2014If we look across the membership, and return map, we see wide variations again. Some smaller funds outperformed the larger ones in 2014.

MemberMapRetail2014The industry funds, of which there are more than 40, did better, with no funds below 8%, even if their peak performance was 14%.

IndustryFunds2014We also see that larger industry funds did better than the smaller ones, on average in 2014.

MemberMapIndustry2014Finally, we look at public sector funds. The 18 funds here did better than retail funds …

PublicSectorSuper2014… and larger funds (by membership) tended to do better.

MemberMapPublicSector2014

Life Insurance Companies Net Profit Up 29.7% In 2015 – APRA

The Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) today released the Quarterly Life Insurance Performance Statistics publication for the March 2015 reference period.

The Quarterly Life Insurance Performance Statistics publication provides industry aggregate summaries of financial performance, financial position, capital adequacy and key ratios in a time series.

Net premium for the industry in the year ended 31 March 2015 was $61.8 billion, up from $50.0 billion in the previous year. Net policy payments for the industry for the same period were $60.8 billion, up from the previous year’s $45.6 billion.

Net profit after tax was $2.6 billion for the year ending 31 March 2015, up from $2.0 billion in the previous year. The March 2015 quarter profit was $830 million compared with the December 2014 quarter profit of $644 million.

The total assets for the industry were $306.5 billion as at 31 March 2015, up from $276.5 billion a year earlier.

The prescribed capital amount coverage ratio for the industry was 1.71 times the prescribed capital amount as at 31 March 2015, down from 1.88 times in the previous year.

Latest RBA Minutes Deliberately Gives No Forward Indication

The RBA released their board minutes from the Monetary Policy Meeting held earlier in May. They continue to balance generally weaker indicators with the risks of stoking the housing market in Sydney and Melbourne with a rate cut. They also agreed that, as at the time of the reduction in the cash rate in February, the statement communicating the decision would not contain any guidance on the future path of monetary policy.

International Economic Conditions

Members noted that growth of Australia’s major trading partners had eased a little in the early months of 2015, but was forecast to remain close to its long-run average in 2015 and 2016. Minor revisions to the outlook largely reflected weaker growth in China in the March quarter, which had also been reflected in lower bulk commodity prices and hence a slightly lower terms of trade than previously forecast by staff. Monetary conditions remained very accommodative across the globe and low oil prices were also supporting growth of Australia’s trading partners. Core inflation rates were below central banks’ targets in many economies.

Economic growth in China had eased further in the March quarter across a broad range of indicators. The Chinese property market had continued to be a source of weakness in the economy and represented a key source of uncertainty for the outlook, both through the effects on demand for industrial products and on the finances of local governments that relied on land sales to fund infrastructure projects. Members noted that residential property prices had continued to fall, albeit at a more gradual pace, and sales were lower than in the previous year. Chinese demand for steel had eased and had been accompanied by a fall in Chinese iron ore production and relatively flat imports of iron ore, although Australian iron ore exports to China continued to grow. Members noted that the authorities had introduced several measures to address the overhang of housing supply, while the People’s Bank of China (PBC) had lowered the reserve requirement ratio for banks.

Although the prices of iron ore, thermal coal and oil prices had rebounded somewhat from recent lows, members observed that the slowing in the growth of Chinese demand for steel had contributed to declines in the prices of bulk commodities since the start of 2015. As a result, the terms of trade had declined and were expected to continue doing so as lower spot prices gradually fed their way into contract prices for commodities, including liquefied natural gas (LNG). Notwithstanding this, members noted that the forecast terms of trade were considerably higher than they had been prior to the mid 2000s.

Growth in the US economy had moderated in the March quarter, largely reflecting the temporary effects of disruptions related to severe weather and industrial action in West Coast ports. Over the same period, conditions in the labour market had continued to improve. Non-farm payrolls employment had continued to grow strongly over the past six months and the unemployment rate had declined further. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) had indicated that it was likely to begin the process of normalising interest rates in the second half of the year as long as economic conditions continued to evolve as expected.

Growth in the Japanese economy looked to have been modest in the March quarter and there were signs that tight labour market conditions were generating stronger wage growth. In the rest of east Asia, growth of both exports and domestic activity appeared to have slowed a little in the March quarter. Economic activity in the euro area had continued to recover gradually over past few months.

Domestic Economic Conditions

Members observed that the forces underpinning developments in the domestic economy were much as they had been for some time. The available data suggested that growth in the domestic economy had continued at a pace a bit below average in the March quarter. Members noted that growth was expected to continue at a similar pace over the coming year before picking up gradually to an above-average pace over the course of 2016/17.

Household consumption growth had picked up late in 2014 and recent indicators were consistent with expectations that consumption would continue to rise gradually, supported by very low interest rates, relatively strong population growth and a gradual decline in the saving ratio. Members noted that if households respond to very low interest rates and higher asset prices to a similar degree as they had in the period prior to the global financial crisis, expected outcomes would include a lower saving ratio and higher consumption growth than embodied in the forecasts. Alternatively, if households were less inclined to bring forward their consumption than had been factored into the forecasts, perhaps to limit the increase in their leverage, consumption growth would be likely to be weaker and the saving ratio higher than forecast.

Conditions in the established housing market had remained strong in Sydney and Melbourne. However, across the rest of the country, which accounts for around 60 per cent of Australia’s dwelling stock, housing price growth had declined. The available data suggested that dwelling investment had grown strongly in the March quarter, supported by low interest rates and above-average population growth. Forward-looking indicators, including residential building and loan approvals, suggested that dwelling investment would continue to grow strongly in the next few quarters. Members noted that growth of housing credit for both owner-occupiers and investors had remained relatively stable in recent months, with overall credit growth broadly in line with longer-term income growth.

Survey data had suggested that business conditions in the non-mining sector were around average and that business credit had picked up of late. However, forward-looking measures of business confidence had remained a little below average and non-residential building approvals had also been running at a relatively low level. Members noted that non-mining business investment was expected to recover later than had been thought at the time the forecasts for the February Statement on Monetary Policy had been prepared. This reassessment was consistent with the weak reading on investment intentions for 2015/16 from the December quarter ABS capital expenditure survey as well as business liaison by the Bank, which had suggested for some time that businesses would commit to increasing investment only after observing a durable improvement in the growth of demand. Members noted that exchange rate developments were also likely to remain important for investment decisions. Uncertainty about both the timing and speed of the recovery in non-mining business investment remained key risks to the forecasts. Mining investment was still expected to decline sharply, but the speed of that decline continued to be uncertain.

Resource export volumes had grown strongly in the March quarter, in part reflecting the absence of substantial weather-related disruptions across the country. Resource exports were expected to continue making a strong contribution to growth as new production, particularly of LNG, came on line over 2015. Members noted that the capacity to maintain production plans in the face of lower commodity prices had been enhanced by further cost-cutting by producers, and that this had been assisted by the decline in the price of oil (an input into production) over the past year.

Fiscal consolidation by the federal and state governments was expected to contribute to subdued growth of domestic demand over the forecast period. Members noted that the Commonwealth Budget, which would be announced the following week, would provide important information for updating these forecasts.

The most recent labour force data indicated that employment growth had been increasing over the past six months or more, to be a little above the rate of population growth. Members noted that the revised labour force data also indicated that the unemployment rate had been stable through most of this period at about 6¼ per cent, and observed that the extended period of slow wage growth may help to reconcile these data with the below-trend growth in the economy over 2014. Forward-looking indicators of labour demand had continued to point to modest growth of employment over coming months.

Members noted that the delayed pick-up in GDP growth in the revised outlook meant that the unemployment rate was forecast to rise further, before starting to decline gradually towards the end of the forecast period. Wage growth was not expected to increase from current low levels for some time. Members discussed the possibility that employment growth could grow fast enough such that the unemployment rate did not increase, especially if there was ongoing moderation in wage growth.

Inflation in the March quarter had been broadly as expected. CPI inflation had slowed over the past year, reflecting the large falls in fuel prices and repeal of the carbon price. Underlying inflation had remained around ½–¾ per cent in the quarter and 2¼–2½ per cent over the past year. Domestic inflationary pressures – as indicated by non-tradables inflation – had remained below average, consistent with the extended period of slower wage growth. Inflation in consumer prices related to housing was marginally above its historical average, driven by inflation in new dwelling costs reflecting the strength of the housing market. Tradables inflation (excluding volatile items and tobacco) had picked up in response to the depreciation of the Australian dollar over the past year or so.

Members noted that the inflation forecast had been revised down slightly since February, reflecting the expectation that growth of economic activity would remain below trend for a little longer than previously forecast. Domestic labour cost pressures were expected to remain well contained and underlying inflation was expected to remain consistent with the inflation target over the forecast period. Headline inflation was forecast to remain below 2 per cent in year-ended terms through to mid 2015, before picking up to be consistent with the inflation target thereafter.

Financial Markets

The Board’s discussion of financial markets commenced with the unusual trading in the Australian dollar in the period immediately prior to the announcement of the Board’s decisions in February, March and April. Members were briefed on the Australian Securities and Investment Commission’s preliminary finding, which had been announced the previous day, that each of those moves in the Australian dollar had been a result of ‘normal market operations in an environment of lower liquidity immediately ahead of the RBA announcement’.

Members observed that financial markets continued to focus on the situation in Greece and monetary policy developments in the major economies.

Negotiations between the Greek Government and its official sector creditors remained at an impasse. Greece appeared to have sufficient funds to meet its scheduled payments in May only after the introduction of further stopgap measures. The next Eurogroup meeting was scheduled for 11 May and at least partial agreement would be needed on Greece’s reform agenda before further assistance funds were released. Overall, Greek banks’ reliance on emergency liquidity assistance had increased significantly recently and total Eurosystem lending to Greek banks now exceeded one-quarter of their total liabilities.

Members noted that the apparent deadlock in Greece had had little impact on broader financial markets until recently, when spreads on the debt of other euro area periphery countries – including Portugal and Spain – had increased as concerns surrounding Greek finances continued to rise.

In contrast, yields on German and other highly rated European sovereign debt fell to new lows in April following the continued expansion of the European Central Bank’s balance sheet, with the 10-year Bund yield declining to 8 basis points. In recent days, however, there had been a marked retracement, with 10 year yields rising by more than 30 basis points in Germany and the United States.

In the United States, market pricing continued to suggest that the first increase in the US policy rate could be closer to the end of the year, and the subsequent pace of policy tightening could be slower than that envisaged by members of the FOMC as published in mid March.

In China, the PBC had taken steps to boost liquidity by reducing the reserve requirement ratio. This step had partly sought to offset the reduction in liquidity resulting from sales of foreign reserves by the PBC in recent months. Equity prices had continued to record particularly large rises in mainland China, leading to prices more than doubling since mid 2014. Members noted that the rally in the Chinese share market had coincided with rapid growth in retail financial investments funded by debt, which raised concerns about the sustainability of the rise in share prices and the potential effects of any decline.

The appreciation of the US dollar since mid 2014 had continued its modest reversal over the past month, resulting in a depreciation of the US dollar against most currencies. Reflecting that, together with recent domestic data, the Australian dollar had appreciated by 3 per cent against the US dollar and by 2½ per cent on a trade-weighted basis over the past month. Nevertheless, compared with its level in mid 2014, the Australian dollar remained around 17 per cent lower against the US dollar and around 10 per cent lower on a trade-weighted basis. In contrast, the Chinese renminbi had been little changed against the US dollar over the past month and in trade-weighted terms remained around 12 per cent above its level in mid 2014.

Members noted that equity prices in the major developed economy markets had risen during April, with the exception of Europe, where equity prices fell a little after large rises earlier in the year. In Australia, equity prices also recorded a small decline in April, although the resources sector had outperformed, with energy sector share prices rising following an increase in the oil price.

Corporate bond issuance by Australian entities remained robust in both domestic and international markets amid favourable pricing conditions. In the money market, pricing on money market instruments pointed to around an 80 per cent chance of a reduction in the cash rate target at the present meeting.

Considerations for Monetary Policy

Members assessed that the outlook for global economic growth had been revised only marginally lower in the near term and would continue to be supported by stimulatory monetary policies and the low price of oil. They noted that growth appeared to have slowed in China and that the weakness in the Chinese property market continued to represent a significant risk both for Chinese growth and demand for construction-related commodities. Lower growth in the demand for commodities had contributed to the lower prices of Australia’s key commodity exports since the beginning of the year. As a result, Australia’s terms of trade were expected to decline a little more than was forecast three months ago.

In their discussion of the appropriate course for monetary policy, members noted the revised staff forecasts for the domestic economy. Although the recent flow of data had been generally positive, there had also been indications that future capital spending in both the mining and non-mining sectors would be weaker than expected. Overall, compared with the previous set of forecasts, growth was now expected to take longer to strengthen and the unemployment rate was likely to remain elevated for longer. This change, and generally subdued growth of domestic costs, including wages, implied that inflation was expected to be slightly lower than in earlier forecasts though still consistent with the target. On the face of it, this meant that it would be appropriate to consider an easing of monetary policy.

Members also discussed the potential risk that low levels of interest rates could foster imbalances in the housing market. While concerned about the very strong pace of growth of housing prices in Sydney, and observing that conditions in Melbourne were strong, members saw much more muted trends in other capital cities. As at previous meetings, they acknowledged the risks that could accompany a sustained increase in leverage from already high levels, should that occur, and that the expansionary effects of lower interest rates could be less than in the past. On the data available for this meeting, however, it did not appear that the growth of housing credit, either for investment or owner-occupancy purposes, had been increasing over recent months. The Bank would continue to work with other regulators to assess and contain the risks arising from the housing market.

More broadly, members noted that the low levels of interest rates were helping to support demand in the face of a number of persistent headwinds and that a further reduction in the cash rate would provide some additional support to economic activity by reinforcing recent encouraging trends in household demand. In turn, this would support non-mining business investment insofar as demand conditions were the main factor constraining these decisions. Such outcomes would be expected ultimately to lead to stronger labour market conditions. Members also noted that further depreciation of the exchange rate seemed to be both likely and necessary, particularly given the significant declines in key commodity prices, and that such an outcome would help to achieve more balanced growth in the economy and assist with the transition to a lower terms of trade.

Members discussed the timing of any interest rate adjustment. They could see cases both for moving at this meeting or at the subsequent meeting. The latter course would bring the advantage of additional information on the economy, including details of the forthcoming Commonwealth Budget. On the other hand, with the revised staff forecasts scheduled to be released a few days after the meeting, members acknowledged that the challenges of communication might be more effectively met with a reduction in the cash rate at this meeting.

On balance, taking all these factors into account, the Board decided that the best course was to ease monetary policy further at this meeting. Members agreed that, as at the time of the reduction in the cash rate in February, the statement communicating the decision would not contain any guidance on the future path of monetary policy. Members did not see this as limiting the Board’s scope for any action that might be appropriate at future meetings.

The Decision

The Board decided to lower the cash rate by 25 basis points to 2.0 per cent, effective 6 May.

Why And How Central Bank Issue Securities

An IMF Working Paper entitled “Issuance of Central Bank Securities: International Experiences and Guidelines” by Simon Gray and Runchana Pongsaparn has been released.

Most emerging market central banks (CBs) have a long history of operating in a context of surplus reserve balances. CB balance sheets in these markets have commonly been ‘asset driven’ whereby the CB takes on certain assets—in particular, foreign exchange (FX) reserves, lending to government, or in some cases lender of last resort (LOLR) assistance to weak banks—whether to serve policy goals or for lack of choice. Doing so generates reserve balances in the accounts of commercial banks which exceed the demand for their use. Since excess reserve balances will tend to depress short-term interest rates (and/or lead to exchange rate pressures), many CBs undertake sterilization operations to minimize adverse consequences. This may involve increasing reserve requirements, paying interest on excess reserves, using instruments such as term deposits, reverse repo (or FX swaps), or the issuance of CB bills.

In recent years a number of advanced economy banking systems have moved from a structural deficit of reserve balances to a structural surplus as a result of the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). In Japan, the U.S. and the U.K. CB purchases of securities (Quantitative Easing (QE)) have resulted in substantial balance sheet increases and large excess reserve positions held by commercial banks, while in the euro zone, liquidity provision via lending to banks, in response to the GFC, has also led to excess reserve balances.

In addition, a surge in cross-border capital flows following the GFC has renewed the challenges for emerging market CBs in the effective management of reserve balances. Initially, many emerging market economies experienced capital outflows as financial institutions pulled liquidity back to the U.S. and Europe. The sale of FX by CBs, to smooth exchange rate depreciation, drained excess domestic-currency reserve balances. But shortly thereafter, loose monetary policy (notably QE) in response to the GFC reignited capital inflows into emerging markets, putting upwards pressure on their domestic currencies. To ward off such pressure, FX intervention has been common, causing an increase in domestic currency reserve balances. To avoid an adverse consequence on financial stability, careful management of such balances is essential.

Issuance of CB securities may be an attractive option for effective ‘liquidity management’ as it provides a degree of autonomy to the CB which is not to be available with all other instruments. Issuance of CB securities represents one of the most marketfriendly approaches and can be considered as one of the major open market operation (OMO) tools for several CBs. Direct instruments such as reserve requirements normally act as a tax on financial intermediation via commercial banks, unless they are fully remunerated. In a number of countries, recently introduced constraints on commercial bank intermediation have led to the growth of non-bank channels (sometimes referred to as ‘shadow banking’), with attendant financial stability risks. The use of other OMO (market friendly) instruments – such as the sale of government securities, or using reverse repurchase and FX swaps—relies necessarily on the availability of collateral (or FX) in the CB’s portfolio. CB securities provide a CB with autonomy in this respect. CB securities could also be used to facilitate bond market development purposes. For some countries, a lack of need from the fiscal side may prevent the government from issuing securities in sufficient amount or range of maturities to meet the market demand for domestic currency credit-risk free assets. Issuance of CB securities can fill in the gap and help establish the benchmark yield curve.

This paper seeks to summarize recent cross-country experiences with issuance of CB securities and draw ‘best practices’ that can serve as an operational guideline for CBs. Existing literature on this particular topic has been rather broad in nature, focusing more on the conceptual side of CB securities issuance. This paper attempts to bridge the conceptual and practical aspects of CB securities issuance, covering such issues as differing maturities of issuance, investor access and secondary market trading.

IMF-CB-IssueThey conclude that CB securities are issued mainly to absorb excess liquidity, and complement other short term market-based liquidity management tools. Recipients of large capital inflows, such as some countries in Asia and Latin America, are more likely to issue CB securities due to the need to sterilize excess liquidity, and able to do so because of a sufficient level of market development. For most countries, CB securities are used to complement other market-based  liquidity management tools such as repo and FX swap but tend to substitute for the use of reserve requirement or government securities.

The ISIMP survey also suggests that inflation targeting countries are more inclined to issue CB securities while low-income countries are least likely to issue them. Inflation targeting CBs would require active liquidity management to steer short-term market rates close to the policy target. CB securities can serve as an effective OMO tool in support this objective. On the other hand, the issuance of CB securities by low-income countries may be hindered by high administrative costs, or the lack of a supportive market infrastructure. While the operational details of CB securities issuance differ across countries, the maturities of securities issued tend to concentrate at the shorter segment of the yield curve. There are of course exceptions especially in the case where excess liquidity is structural and there is insufficient government bond supply. Importantly, the plan of CB securities issuance should be closely coordinated with that of the government to ensure consistency and facilitate well-functioning and appropriate development of the sovereign domestic bond market.

The paper also provides some general guidelines on the four major building blocks of CB securities issuance. The guidelines encompass several important steps—from the planning stage (which includes for instance liquidity forecasting, allocation of OMO instruments and market assessment), auction process (whether and how to allow for discretion in the allocation of bids) and post-auction assessment. Drawing on international experiences, these steps provide CBs some guidance on best practices on the operational aspects of CB securities issuance.

Note that IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.

 

Islamic Financial Products And Banking Regulation

An IMF Working Paper entitled “Islamic Finance, Consumer Protection, and Financial Stability” by Inutu Lukong has been released. This is relevant because Islamic finance is growing rapidly in value and geographical reach. The banking sector is now systemically important in a dozen countries and growing in many other countries.

Consumers of Islamic financial products have increased to critical proportions, thus consumer protection frameworks that cater to the specifics of Islamic financial products should be an integral part of regulatory frameworks in countries where the industry exists. Although still a small share of global finance, Islamic finance is growing rapidly in value and geographical reach. The banking sector is now systemically important in a dozen countries and growing in many other countries. By end December 2013, consumers of Islamic banking products were estimated at 30 million (Enerst and Young (2013)). The Sukuk market has also registered phenomenal growth; the structures have become increasingly complex; and the issuer base has broadened to include advanced, emerging market and developing countries on one hand, and sovereigns and corporates on the other. The growing complexity of products can make it difficult for consumers and investors to discern risks while the broadening of issuers exposes investors to differing counterparty risks.

In the aftermath of the global financial crisis, many countries integrated consumer protection in their regulatory frameworks, but progress has been uneven across countries and few have tailored the frameworks to address the unique risks of Islamic finance. A number of international bodies, including the Islamic Financial Standards Board (IFSB), the Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI); and the International Islamic Financial Market (IIFM), have issued standards to cater to the specifics of the Islamic finance industry, but adoption of the standards has been uneven across countries and the development of standards is still evolving.

This paper aims to contribute to ongoing efforts to strengthen the architecture for consumer protection in Islamic finance as part of the broader effort to safeguard the sound development of the sector. Outside the work of the regulatory bodies, research on the protection of consumers of Islamic financial products is limited and remaining gaps in the regulatory architecture for consumer protection in Islamic finance have not been assessed. The few studies on consumer protection in Islamic finance include the paper by Mamhood [2012] which analyzed the prospects of extending an Investor Protection Framework to the Islamic Capital Market in Malaysia; the IFSB [2013] paper that analyzes product regulation that could foster stronger protection for consumers of Islamic financial products; and the IFSB/IOSCO [2013] joint review on issues, risks and challenges arising from potential inadequate disclosure in the areas of Sukuk and Islamic Collective Investment Schemes.

The paper focuses on Islamic banking products and Sukuk, which together account for 95 percent of the Islamic finance industry. It highlights sources of information asymmetries that can result in consumers making uninformed decisions, as well as potential avenues for consumer exploitation in the design of Islamic financial products that could affect the sound development of the industry. It also evaluates the adequacy of current legal and regulatory frameworks for consumer protection, and discusses policy options for strengthening them. The analysis is based on the experiences of a sample of countries, including Bahrain, Egypt, Iran, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Malaysia, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, the United Arab Emirates, the United Kingdom and Yemen.

The main conclusions of the paper are that Shar’iah principles, which govern Islamic finance, provide a strong foundation for consumer protection, but the features alone cannot guarantee adequate protection for consumers, because not all providers are motivated by ethical precepts, and the practice sometimes deviate from the principles. Consumer protection frameworks for conventional financial products are relevant to Islamic finance, but they need some adaptation to address risks specific to Islamic financial products. In particular, reforms are needed to address consumer vulnerabilities from current practices with respect to Profit Sharing Investment Accounts (PSIA), Ijārah Muntahia Bittamlīk, and conventional deposit insurance schemes as well as to address the legal risks for investors in Sukuk, particularly in cross border default cases.

Note that IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.

Fast-track Could Help Roll Back Dodd-Frank

Simon Johnson, Professor of Global Economics and Management at MIT Sloan School of Management writes in The Conversation that Sen Warren is right: fast-track could help roll back Dodd-Frank

Earlier this month Senator Elizabeth Warren suggested that the Trade Promotion Authority (TPA) bill currently before Congress could make it easier, in the future, to roll back Dodd-Frank financial reforms. The reaction from the Obama administration was an immediate rebuttal, including from the president himself.

And a number of commentators joined the president’s side of the argument, claiming that Senator Warren’s concerns were hypothetical or far-fetched.

On this issue, however, Senator Warren is entirely correct, and President Obama and his supporters appear to have completely misunderstood the risks of passing TPA, dubbed fast-track, in its current form – which after some snags appears to be close to a vote in the Senate.

What TPA means in practice

The Trade Promotion Authority is a procedure for passing trade agreement-implementing legislation through Congress.

Under TPA, Congress agrees in advance to consider implementing legislation – such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) – on an up-or-down basis. Members can vote for or against, but they cannot offer amendments.

In the House of Representatives, this amounts to promising to adopt a particular rule for implementing legislation when proposed. In practice, however, those rules are controlled by the House leadership – and they can always decide that a particular piece of legislation will be considered without amendments being allowed.

When the House leadership wants a trade agreement – as the Republicans want the TPP – then fast-track does not have much impact on the House side for free trade agreement-implementing legislation.

The real impact is on the Senate side. Here TPA would commit the Senate to vote on TPP – and any future trade agreements while TPA is in effect – without allowing any potential filibuster. So the support of only 50 senators would be needed (as the vice president can break a tie) rather than 60.

How Dodd-Frank is at risk

Dodd-Frank financial reform and regulation issues are not central, as far as we know, to the Trans-Pacific Partnership, but they are absolutely on the table in the upcoming free trade agreement with the European Union, known as the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP).

TTIP is still being negotiated, but the Europeans have said publicly and repeatedly – including recently – that they would like to include a great deal about financial regulation in this agreement. And important parts of the US and European financial sector lobby are egging them on.

The current Treasury Department is adamantly opposed to including such issues, precisely because it would impede the working of financial regulation in general and implementation of Dodd-Frank in particular. (For more details, see this Policy Brief that I wrote with Jeffrey J. Schott, my colleague at the Peterson Institute for International Economics.)

But the term of the TPA, as currently proposed, is six years. (To be precise, it is for three years, renewable for another three, but the terms of renewal are almost automatic. And as long as the Republicans control the House of Representatives in 2017-18, it will be renewed.)

If the next president agreed to amend Dodd-Frank as part of TTIP, he or she would include those changes in the bill that implements it, with no Congressional amendments allowed to strip out the financial changes.

Any direct Dodd-Frank repeal attempt in 2017 or later would presumably be subject to potential filibuster in the Senate – and as long as Democrats can control at least 41 seats, they can block it. But TPA would allow TTIP to pass the Senate with a simple majority.

The GOP’s back door to rolling back Dodd-Frank

If a Republican is elected president in November 2016, it is likely the Republicans will control the House and have a majority in the Senate – but not 60 votes. So a Dodd-Frank rollback through TTIP would be entirely feasible and easier to implement (for a Republican president in that scenario) than any kind of direct attack on the law.

The odds of this scenario are roughly the same as that of a Republican being elected president in 2016. (The latest polls show the two parties are neck-and-neck to win the White House.)

To be clear, the TPP and TTIP agreements will involve and require changes to US law, assuming specific tariffs are reduced or eliminated (and the same goes for many changes to non-tariff barriers). If a trade agreement didn’t require such changes, we wouldn’t need an implementing bill.

Politicians are often criticized for not looking sufficiently far ahead. Ironically, Senator Warren is being criticized for doing just that, applying the logic of the Obama Treasury (in not wanting financial regulation included in TTIP) and pointing out that the TPA would greatly increase the probability of exactly what the president claims he does not want: a significant or substantial legislative repeal of Dodd-Frank on any number of dimensions.

In addition, TTIP could have a chilling effect on regulation and even the supervision of finance. This is precisely why big banks are so keen to get financial regulation into TTIP.

Was it a mistake?

Why doesn’t the White House simply thank Senator Warren for pointing out this potential problem – and move to limit the term of TPA? The Republicans want TPP and soon; they would vote for a TPA that expires at the end of 2016.

President Obama says that he would do nothing to facilitate the rollback of Dodd-Frank. But his administration did exactly that with the repeal of Section 716 in December (Section 716 limited the ability of big banks to bet heavily on derivatives).

Senator Warren and others on Capitol Hill fought hard against that repeal, wanting to keep this sensible restriction on big banks. But at the decisive moments the White House pushed strongly in the other direction.

Has the White House made a simple and perhaps embarrassing mistake by seeking TPA that runs for six years? Or does the Obama administration know exactly what it is doing when it opens the backdoor to undermining its own signature Dodd-Frank legislation? The latter, unfortunately, seems more likely.

Risks In Financial Markets And Shadow Banks

Andrew Bailey, Deputy Governor, Prudential Regulation and Chief Executive Officer, Prudential Regulation Authority gave a speech at  Cambridge University – Financial Markets: identifying risks and appropriate responses – which discusses important concepts in relation to the effective supervision of Financial Markets, in the context of expanding bond markets and automated electronic trading. There is good evidence that financial market conditions have evolved in ways that reduce the likelihood of continuous market liquidity in all states

There is a commonly-held narrative about the financial crisis that the banks caused it, and the solution is more regulation of both an economy-wide (macro-prudential in the jargon) and firm specific  (micro-prudential) type. But it isn’t that simple, and tonight I want to outline the role of financial markets and non-bank institutions (which sometimes go under the somewhat pejorative term of shadow banks ) within the overall financial system and describe how, with sufficient resilience, they play a number of key roles in the financial system, including offering borrowers alternatives to bank lending. Nevertheless, I also want to explain why there is significant and increasing emphasis on the risks they can pose to financial stability. Put simply, it is quite often said that we are living in unprecedented times in the performance of financial markets.

The simple narrative around banks is that they over-extended themselves (over-leveraged in terms of the ratio of assets to capital and over-extended in terms of the ratio of illiquid to liquid assets) in the run-up to the crisis, and the resulting problems had two closely linked and malign effects: first, the crisis jeopardised the provision of those core financial services which banks provide and on which all of us depend; and second, by so doing – and being too big or complicated to deal with as failed companies – they required the use of taxpayers’ money to bail them out. That’s the story, and it explains why the public policy actions taken both immediately after the crisis (bail-outs) and the subsequent post-crisis reforms have been directed at protecting those or core financial services and seeking to ensure that taxpayers’ money does not need to be put at risk.

There is however more to the story than that. In the period between the early 1990s and the onset of the crisis, there was a remarkable and unprecedented evolution of the financial system which involved a major expansion of activity. Banks moved from a traditional model of taking deposits and lending them out, to a model that involved far more the origination and distribution of loans – often known often as securitisation, in which these loans were substantially distributed to shadow banks. These shadow banks thereby took on more of the traditional core bank functions of credit assessment and maturity transformation (the practice of borrowing at shorter maturities than the maturities of the assets they held). And, they did so, like the banks, with weak levels of capital.

But, it would be a mistake to portray shadow banks as bad. There is good evidence that in the twenty years before the crisis they emerged as a stabilising force (most notably in the US) because they were able to expand their provision of credit at times when traditional bank lending underwent cyclical contractions. That said, there were some troubling properties associated with the growth of shadow banking. For instance, quite a few were sponsored by banks as a means to reduce the amount of capital to be held against risk exposures. When the crisis hit, in a number of cases those banks found they had to stand behind their offshoots for contractual or reputational reasons, so the separation was illusory and led to greater leverage in the system. Another issue was that the originate and distribute model of securitisation was often opaque and led to insufficient genuine risk transfer away from the banking system, in ways that became very problematic when the crisis hit. Shadow banks, also neglected the funding side of their balance sheets, so that they came to depend upon using their assets as security to obtain funding, often from banks. This is quite different from the traditional model of deposit funded banking where the assets (loans) are not used as security for raising funds. However, it must be said that in the run-up to the crisis, banks too came to depend overly on such secured funding. When the crisis hit, the value of the assets used as security for collateral fell, funding conditions tightened and in some instances were cut off .

These weaknesses meant that the counterbalancing behaviour of shadow banks vanished. Instead, they retracted just as banks did, but much more violently, which exacerbated the magnitude of the crisis. The result was therefore greater volatility in financial markets, and a dramatic increase in the vulnerability of economies to financial shocks. This contraction in credit supply was thus a powerful channel through which the financial sector hit economies. The result was the largest contraction in real economic activity since the Great Depression. In the better times, securitisation and the shadow banking system appeared to have reduced the sensitivity of the aggregate supply of lending and thus the sensitivity of the real economy to transitions in bank funding conditions. But they did not do so at the point it would have been most valuable, during the global crisis. As Stanley Fischer has recently put it: “when non-banks pulled back, other parts of the system suffered. When non-banks failed other parts of the system failed.”).

The originate to distribute model created tradeable assets – the securities in securitisation. The success of the model depended on there being liquid secondary markets for these securities. In its broadest sense, market liquidity refers to the ease with which one asset can be traded for another, and thus different markets can be more or less liquid. The level of liquidity in financial markets depends on among other things the amount of arbitrage or market making capacity and whether specialised dealers (market makers) will step in as buyers or sellers in response to temporary imbalances in supply and demand (Fender and Lewrick 2015). In what appeared to be normal times before the crisis, there was abundant capacity to maintain liquidity in markets, supported by banks and shadow banks such as hedge funds.

But during the crisis, such capacity became much more scarce or even undeployed, and market liquidity dried up. The key point here is that the originate to distribute approach depended on continuous liquidity in financial markets, and when that dried up in the crisis the effects were severe.

I want to move on now to what has happened since the crisis. Financial market activity has grown rapidly. There are many statistics that could be quoted, so to choose one, over the last 15 years, global bond markets have grown from around $30 trillion in 2000 to nearly $90 trillion today. That is a lot, not least because in the middle of that 15 year period came the global financial crisis. Therefore, when it comes to the task of maintaining market liquidity, there is a lot more to hold up. Also, the broad investment or asset management sector is now much larger, at around $75 trillion at end-2013. Thus, in the wake of the financial crisis there has been a substantial increase in the intermediation of credit via financial markets rather than long-term on the balance sheets of banks, involving both the supply of new credit to borrowers and the absorption of assets coming out of the banking system, as banks reduce their balance sheets.

Over the same period, there has been a fundamental and rapid change in the microstructure of financial markets – the organisation of how they work. Electronic platforms are increasingly used in a number of major financial markets (notably equity and foreign exchange markets). As part of that change, automated trading – which is a subset of electronic trading using algorithms to determine trading decisions – has become common in those markets. And, within automated trading, there has been growth in high frequency trading – which relies on speed of execution to get ahead of other market players . While electronic trading has contributed to increasing market efficiency and probably reducing transaction costs, there are also risks that arise from trading strategies that are flawed, or where in constructing the strategy not all possible outcomes were considered, including the ability to trade large blocks.

To recap, the last two decades have seen major changes in the financial system. These have, in turn, shaped the impact of the global financial crisis and its aftermath. I want now to look at the aftermath of that crisis and pick out several developments that are important for understanding current and future risks to financial stability.

The first development concerns the overall pattern of activity in financial markets. While the size of global bond markets has grown rapidly, the evidence indicates that trading volumes in a number of markets have declined. Bond inventories held by primary dealers have likewise reduced, bid-ask spreads have risen in the corporate bond markets, and it has become more expensive to hedge named credit risk using derivatives. A key point here is that the balance sheets of dealers active in these markets have shrunk markedly, with many fewer firms active in market-making.

Markets have grown, but the capacity to maintain liquidity – as judged by the market–making capacity of the major banks and broker-dealers – has declined . As my colleague Chris Salmon recently put it, this reduction in market making capacity has been associated with increased concentration in many bond markets, as firms have become more discriminating about the markets they make, or the clients they serve. But this trend has gone hand-in-hand with a growth in assets under management, with important implications for the provision of liquidity by market makers in times of stress in those markets.).

The second post-crisis development is the natural consequence of the severity of the crisis and its impact on real economies. The extraordinary (by historical standards) degree of monetary policy easing by central banks was followed by a fall in volatility in financial markets. Markets appeared to come to take comfort from their own mantra of “low-for-long” rates which in turn incentivised a “search for yield” (to be clear, “low for long” has not been in the phraseology of central banks).

Studies of the US Treasury market have indicated that the Federal Reserve’s programme of Quantitative Easing (QE) caused a reduction in the liquidity premium return for holding those bonds. Part of the effect of QE programmes is to improve market conditions for the targeted asset classes but also to see the trickle down to other asset classes as market conditions change more generally). To be clear however, QE asset purchase operations were not designed to tackle a liquidity problem in the financial system. Rather, the impact on liquidity was one of the channels through which QE has affected the real economy and thus has had its intended effect in monetary policy terms. While estimates of the impact of QE are inherently uncertain, one of the desired outcomes of central bank asset purchases is to lower yields thus affecting longer term interest rates and creating a positive economic effect. In doing so, QE can improve the functioning of financial markets by reducing liquidity premia.

The third post-crisis development is the impact of the growth of automated trading in financial markets, and the challenges this poses for maintaining continuous market and liquidity. Over the last year volatility in many financial markets has picked up from a low base and we have seen some acute but short-lived incidents of extreme volatility and impaired liquidity in secondary markets. On 15 October last year there was unprecedented volatility in the US Treasury market, and on 15 January this year there was substantial volatility in the Swiss Franc exchange rate following the unexpected decision by the Swiss National Bank to remove its Europe/Swiss Franc floor. Now, central banks are known for their powers of understatement, so what do I mean by words like “unprecedented” and “substantial”. On 15 October, 10 year US Treasury yields moved intra-day by around 8 standard deviations of preceding daily changes. On 15 January, the Swiss Franc moved by more than 30 standard deviations. For rough scale, an 8 standard deviation move should happen once every three billion years or so for normally distributed data.

You may at this point recall the saying popularised by Mark Twain, about “lies, damned lies and statistics”. I think I can be reasonably confident in saying that the fact of these events happening does not mean that we should expect low volatility in financial markets for at least the next three billion years.

I am not going to spend time discussing the causes of these events; suffice to say that there was news of an unexpected sort, and the size of the resulting moves points to greater sensitivity in the response of markets. The ability of markets to trade without triggering major price moves was limited. That said, by the end of both days, volatility had reduced, prices had retraced a portion of their peak intra-day moves and liquidity returned. This quick stabilisation helped to limit contagion to other markets, and thus wider effects on the stability of the financial system. Should we therefore be concerned? My answer to that is we should certainly be keenly interested. I agree with the conclusion of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York that understanding the manner in which the evolving market structure is affecting market liquidity, efficiency and pricing is highly important ). This conclusion has been reinforced in the recent publication of the Senior Supervisors Group (SSG) in which the PRA participates). The SSG has concluded that “key supervisory concerns centre on whether the risks associated with algorithmic trading have outpaced control improvements. The extent to which algorithmic trading activity, including HFT, is adequately captured in banks’ risk management frameworks, and whether standard risk management tools are effective for monitoring the risks associated with this activity, are areas of inquiry that all supervisors need to explore”.

As supervisors of almost all of the world’s major trading banks – through their operations in London – we can provide some helpful assessment of these events. We have observed that the balance between aggregate buy and sell orders submitted to banks’ electronic trading systems can shift instantaneously, and sometimes violently, upon this type of occurrence. The impact is often exacerbated by the simultaneous reduction in order book depth on organised multilateral electronic trading venues. The electronic trading contribution was more evident on 15 January, as a foreign currency market event than the 15 October (a bond market event), reflecting the different patterns of trading in these markets.

On the 15 January, the ability of banks’ e-trading systems to hedge positions consistently through automatic risk management broke down as the necessary reference prices became discontinuous and unreliable. The algorithms of automatic trading have rules embedded in their code such that quotes are immediately pulled if there is a severe market liquidity event. Moreover, the algorithms often have automatic rules that activate circuit breakers or so-called “kill switches” should the aggregate notional risk on a firm’s book exceed programmed limits. On 15 January, the algorithms acted quickly to pull the so-called “streaming prices” when liquidity in the reference market for these prices dried up. Where this did not happen simultaneously, it resulted in large open positions being accumulated by the banks, quite literally within seconds, as an overwhelming balance of client sell orders were automatically executed. Once pre-determined risk accumulation limits had been breached the algorithms instantaneously shut down. Whilst each algorithm, operating independently, may well have been quite prudently calibrated to protect the bank from building an exposure that exceeded its risk appetite, collectively, the impact on market liquidity was akin, albeit temporarily, to a cascading failure across a power grid.

As a consequence, the foreign exchange market reverted to human voice orders as the substitute for automated trading. There were therefore outcomes that appear not to have been expected. So, at the risk of quoting Shakespeare inappropriately, all was well that ended (reasonably) well, but the risk that this would not be the outcome is too great to ignore.

In summary, there is good evidence that financial market conditions have evolved in ways that reduce the likelihood of continuous market liquidity in all states. One element of this is the response of regulators to the financial crisis (to which I will return later), while the other is a product of the rapid development of technology and trading strategies. The effects have probably been offset to some degree by beneficial influences from central bank monetary policy actions which have increased market liquidity. Measures of risk that reflect the overall demand for and supply of financial assets, including liquidity risk premia, remain low by historical standards, notwithstanding recent events. In part, this likely reflects the continued intended effects of monetary policy setting and the communication of policy looking forward. This has, as intended, provided an incentive for risk-taking by investors, and thus the market environment has been conducive to the so-called “search for yield”.

But, as described, underlying conditions in financial markets suggest that the current situation could be fragile . Shocks that might prompt large-scale asset disposals are of particular concern. The global asset management industry is both large in size in its own right and relative to the size of the commercial banking system.

A key issue is the degree to which asset managers (or shadow banks) typically offer short-term redemptions against potentially illiquid assets. This capacity to realise assets without unwanted disturbance to financial markets is therefore critical and is shaping the work of authorities. The risk is inherently global in nature, thereby suggesting that internationally–coordinated policy action is the preferred outcome where necessary.  In the rest of my time, I will describe the work that is being done on policy responses.

First, I want to challenge the argument that the issue derives from the re-regulation of the capital and liquidity positions of banks that have in the past acted as market-makers, and thus marginal investors. This argument has a number of strands: capital and funding costs for dealer inventories in banks and broker-dealers have increased; the cost of hedging with single name credit default swaps has risen, causing availability to drop; proprietary trading restrictions (e.g. the Volcker Rule in the US) limit market making (it is too hard to distinguish prop trading from market making); and increased trade transparency requirements restrict market liquidity.)

If we look at the US as the prime example, the evidence indicates that the big run-up in inventories of fixed income securities held by the primary dealers occurred from around 2003-04 onwards, reached a peak in 2008, and has then settled back to around the 2002 level over the last two years, or so.

BOE!8May2015Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, as reproduced in the Bank of England Financial Stability Report – December 2014

Looked at in this light, the increase in inventory capacity in the dealer community was ephemeral, reflecting the underpricing of risk, a weak capital regime and the subsidy provided to the major banks by implicit government guarantees. Dealers de-risked their balance sheets rapidly as the crisis hit, and this reminds us that their capacity and willingness to stand in the way of major market moves (akin to catching a falling knife) was always constrained . And all of this happened before any new regulations were put in place.

Last on this point, it is worth recalling the background to the large increase in inventories from around 2002/04. Here, regulation does appear to have played a role, and not a good one. The first amendment to the Basel I capital standard came in the mid 1990s in the form of the so-called Market Risk Amendment. It enabled a substantial reduction in the capital held against trading book assets such as inventories, to a level that could be less than 1% of those assets. To illustrate this point, here is a quote from the FSA’s report into the failure of RBS.

“The capital regime was more deficient, moreover, in respect of the trading books of the banks ….. the acquisition of ABN AMRO meant that RBS’s trading book assets almost doubled between end 2006 and end 2007. The low risk weights assigned to trading assets suggested that only £2.3 billion of core tier 1 capital was held to cover potential trading losses which might result from assets carried at around £470 billion on the firm’s balance sheet.

In fact, in 2008 losses of £12.2 billion arose in the credit trading area along (a subset of total trading book assets). A regime which inadequately evaluated trading book risks was, therefore, fundamental to RBS’s failure.”).

I do not doubt that the reversal of this capital treatment of trading books has had an impact on dealer inventory levels by increasing the capital intensity. But I don’t accept that the fairly ephemeral position that emerged shortly before the crisis was fit for purpose or sustainable.

What are we therefore doing about the fragility of market liquidity and the risks to both financial stability and the state of the real economy that arise from it? First, we are working hard to understand better these risks and how they could manifest themselves. As the Bank of England’s Financial Policy Committee stated at the end of March, our concern is that investment allocations and the pricing of some securities “may presume that asset sales can be performed in an environment of continuous market liquidity.” (FPC (2015))

We are: gathering better data and thus building a greater understanding of the channels through which market liquidity can affect financial stability and economic activity; establishing a better understanding of how asset managers form their strategies for managing liquidity in their funds in normal and stressed conditions (taking into account any increase that might have occurred in the correlations between various market participants’ trading activities, such as the use of passive investment strategies); and deepening our knowledge of the contributors to greater fragility of market liquidity. The FPC has asked for a full report on these issues when it meets in September and an interim report in June.

Globally, the Financial Stability Board also has set priorities for its work, with which we are fully engaged. The intention is to understand and address vulnerabilities in capital market and asset management activities, focussing on both near-term risk channels and the options that currently exist to address them, the longer-term development of these markets and whether additional policy tools should be applied to asset managers according to the activities they undertake, with the aim of mitigating systemic risks.

The PRA, as the UK’s prudential supervisor of major trading firms, will continue to develop its capacity to assess algorithmic or automated trading, including the governance and controls around the introduction and maintenance of trading algorithms, and the potential system-wide impact of crowded positions and market liquidity. We will assess the adequacy of existing risk measurement and management practices in capturing exposures from the large volume of intraday trading instigated by these algorithms. We will continue to develop our assessment of whether trading controls deployed around algorithmic trading are fit for purpose, and in doing so we will no doubt capture insights on the role of market making on electronic platforms. This is all part of our task of supervising firms’ trading books. It should be assisted by the introduction of MIFID2 (the Markets and Financial Instruments Directive) in Europe, which will impose rules on algorithms and high frequency trading, including the introduction of circuit breakers, minimum tick sizes and maximum order-to-trade ratios, thereby seeking to improve the stability of markets.

It might be possible to conclude that it is all work to understand the problem rather than fix it. Not so, and I want to end by summarising six areas where action is already under way to reduce impediments to the development of diverse and sustainable market based finance.

First, maintaining the stability of the financial system means that we have to keep a close watch on how risks that can appear in financial markets and the non-bank financial system may wash back into and affect the critical functions performed by banks; in other words destabilise the core of the system. In order to enhance our protection against this risk, in this year’s Bank of England concurrent stress test, we are taking a substantial step to enhance the coverage of market risks. Our new approach to stress testing trading activities will capture how fast banks could unwind or hedge their trading positions in the stress scenario. This means positions that are less liquid under stress conditions will receive larger shocks. And, we have developed a new approach to stressing counterparty credit risk, which focusses on capturing losses from exposures that would become large under the stress scenario and for counterparties that would be most vulnerable in the stress scenario.

Second, the Bank of England, working with the FCA and HM Treasury has set up the Fair and Effective Markets Review to restore trust and confidence in the fixed income, currency and commodity (FICC) markets in the wake of the serious wave of misconduct seen since the height of the financial crisis. The Review is taking a fundamental look at the root causes of these abuses, the steps that have already been taken by firms and regulators to put things right, and what more is needed to deliver less vulnerable market structures and raise standards of behaviour in future. The Review will publish its recommendations in June 2015. Out of this assessment, and based on consultations to date, will I believe come priorities on market structure “standards” and transparency, effective competition, professional culture within firms and effective, pre-emptive supervision which reduces the drama of ex-post enforcement.

The third area of action concerns initiatives to improve the functioning of markets to support activity in real economies. Resilient market-based financing will help to support sustainable economic growth. The aim behind the European Commission initiative on Capital Markets Union is to strengthen markets in the EU to support growth and stability, and sustainable progress on this front will be welcome . Likewise, sound securitisation is a goal of the wider financial reform programme. The Bank of England and the ECB have published a consultation paper to identify simple, transparent and comparable securitisation techniques, the use of which should be encouraged. This work is now being taken forward in international policymaking bodies.

The fourth area of activity involves so-called securities financing transactions (SFTs) including securities lending and repurchase (repo) agreements. These can have the beneficial effects of supporting price discovery in financial markets and secondary market liquidity, and are important as part of market-making activities by financial firms, as well as their investment and risk management activities. But, as we witnessed in the crisis, they can also be a source of excessive leverage and mismatches in liquidity positions. As a consequence, some of these markets shrank rapidly as the crisis took hold. The Financial Stability Board has taken steps to introduce haircuts on SFTs that are not centrally cleared, with the aim of preventing excessive leverage becoming available to shadow banks in a boom, thereby reducing the procycliality of that leverage. The haircuts set an upper limit on the amount that banks and broker-dealers can lend against securities of different credit quality.

The fifth area concerns the risk of asset managers offering short-term redemptions to investors against potentially illiquid securities. The proportion of assets held in such structures has increased over the past decade. Given more fragile underlying market liquidity, for the reasons I have described, stressed disposals of assets might be harder to accommodate in an orderly fashion. The international securities regulatory body IOSCO, issued recommendations in 2012 that provide a basis for Common Standards for Money Market Funds (MMFs) across jurisdictions, in particular seeking to ensure that MMFs are not susceptible to the risk of runs (in the way that banks can be). More broadly, work continues on putting into practice appropriate policies and standards to prevent the risk of disorderly sales of assets in the face of investor withdrawals. Potential responses (and at this stage we are looking at options in an open way) are to require funds to hold larger liquid asset buffers to facilitate orderly redemption payments to investors, to apply more stringent leverage limits where appropriate, and to require that the redemption terms offered to investors take sufficient account of the risk that secondary market liquidity in the assets they hold could become impaired. These are possibilities, but at this stage very much not policies for the reason that a lot more work is need to properly assess them.

Last, central banks can back-stop market liquidity by acting as market makers of the last resort.  The Bank of England had described in its so-called Red Book how it could act in such a way in exceptional circumstances. Here too, there is a lot more to be done to consider the circumstances in which this tool could be used.

Conclusion

The rapid trend towards greater use of market-based financing is one that should be welcomed. But, it is important that accompanying risks to financial stability are well understood and managed. Credit creation since the financial crisis has been heavily reliant on market based finance in the UK and internationally. We have to be alert to, and ready to handle the risks and consequences of any reversal in market conditions. Recent incidents of market volatility act as a reminder that it can disappear very quickly in more normal as well as stressed times. Moreover the business models of the broker-dealers that act as market makers are changing in response to the financial crisis and they are becoming reluctant to absorb large positions. In my view those changes are inevitable, because the pre-crisis state of affairs was ephemeral and unsustainable. But the impact of the change is of course important for both monetary policy and financial stability, because it affects the supply of credit to the economy and the stability of the financial system. My assessment is that in terms of understanding the risks and framing possible mitigating actions, we will fare better if we start by focussing on the activities that create such market risk, and then as appropriate move on to the entities that house those activities.

The policy response from the authorities is by nature an activity that needs to be carried out through close international co-ordination. The Bank of England is committed to playing its part, consistent with the major presence of financial market activity in the UK, alongside and as a part of the work of the G20 under the auspices of the Financial Stability Board.

Rental Yields Fall – CoreLogic RP Data

According to analysis from CoreLogic RP Data, rental rates across the combined capital cities increased by 0.1% in April and continue to rise at their slowest annual pace in more than a decade. While rental rates tell part of the story, it is also important to consider rental yields. Rental yields for houses and units are sitting at their lowest level since late 2010. There is a reason for the disconnect between rising house prices and rents. That is simply because rents are more directly linked to average incomes than home values. As we reported recently, income growth is slowing.

Across the combined capital cities, gross rental yields are recorded at 3.6% for houses and 4.5% for units. At the same time in 2014, gross rental yields were recorded at 3.8% for houses and 4.6% for units. Across the individual capital cities, house rental yields are lowest in Melbourne (3.2%) and Sydney (3.4%) and highest in Darwin (5.7%) and Hobart (5.2%). RPDataRentalsApril2015Across most cities house rental yields are lower now than they were at the same time last year, the exceptions are Brisbane, Adelaide and Hobart where they are unchanged. At 3.4%, rental yields in Sydney are the lowest they’ve been since May 2005 and at 3.2 per cent Melbourne yields are at their lowest level since November 2010. The unit market shows different trends to the detached housing market with yields higher or unchanged over the year across most cities. Unit yields are lowest in Melbourne (4.2%) and Sydney (4.3%) and highest in Darwin (5.9%) and Brisbane (5.4%). Unit yields in Sydney are at their lowest level since August 2005 while yields in Melbourne have edged higher over the past month.

RPDataYieldsApril2015Across the combined capital cities, rental rates are recorded at $487 per week and they have risen by 0.1% over the month, 0.7% over the past three months and by 1.7% over the past 12 months. Although rental rates are still increasing, they are doing so at a moderate rate. In fact, the annual rate of growth has been recorded at 1.7% for four consecutive months and hasn’t previously been this low since June 2003. The slow pace of rental appreciation can likely be attributed to the booming level of dwelling construction coupled with high levels of buying activity from the investment segment which is adding additional rental stock to the market and curtailing rental increases. Looking across the capital cities, over the past year Sydney and Hobart have recorded the greatest increases in weekly rents. Rents have fallen over the past three months in Perth and Darwin; along with Canberra these cities have recorded rental falls over the year, down -4.2%, -4.7% and -2.6% respectively.

Looking at the performance of houses as opposed to units there isn’t a great deal of difference in the rates of rental appreciation. House rents were recorded at $492 per week across the combined capital cities in April 2015 compared to $461 per week for units. House rents have recorded stronger growth over the month (0.1%) compared to unit rents which fell by -0.1%. Over the quarter unit rental growth (0.6%) has been lower than houses (0.7%) however, over the past year units have recorded slightly stronger rental growth (1.9%) than houses (1.6%).
Comparing the current rate of rental growth with the 10 year average annual rate of rental appreciation highlights that rental growth is currently sluggish across all cities. In fact, the ten year average annual rate of rental growth is higher than the current growth rate in each capital city. The slower pace of rental growth may be attributed to a number of factors including: a ramp-up in investment purchases resulting in an increase in rental stock, an increase in housing supply which has also added to rental stock and a reduction in net overseas migration decreasing demand for rental stock.

Rental rates are already increasing at their slowest annual rate in more than a decade and the outlook is that a low rate of growth will continue. In fact, with residential construction activity continuing to increase, particularly for inner city units, we would expect that the additional housing supply may result in an even lower rate of rental growth over the coming months. This is likely to be most evident in the markets where new unit supply is surging, being Melbourne and Brisbane and to a lesser extent Sydney.