Deposit Safety Is A Matter Of Confidence

Last week the Bank of England Governor raised the prospect of changes to the Deposit Insurance schemes which exists in many Western Economies. So we look at what he said, and consider the relative security of deposits in the banking system, in the light of recent failures, and Central Bank interventions.

For more on Deposit Bail-In see my recent posts here:

Is Deposit Bail-In A Thing In Australia? https://youtu.be/B8OC2izjKuA

Deposit Bail-In: Who’s Fact-checking The Fact-checkers? With Robbie Barwick https://youtu.be/CAXprMwMnyY

The Deposit Bail In Question… https://youtu.be/n8t-78n1Lrs

http://www.martinnorth.com/

Go to the Walk The World Universe at https://walktheworld.com.au/

Deposit Insurance Is No Protection Against Bail-In Risk

In the next part of our series Economist John Adams and Analyst Martin North consider the relationship between Deposit Insurance and Bail-In. Things are not straightforward.

It’s Too Late – Bail-In Has Already Happened!

Solicitor Confirms That Bail-In Of Deposits IS Legal

https://www.adamseconomics.com/post/deposit-insurance-is-no-protection-against-bail-in

Deposit Insurance Where The Insurer Has No Money To Pay…

As we commence a series on the Deposit Insurance Scheme and Deposit Bail-In, we reprise a show we recorded in 2018 on the DFA channel where Economist John Adams and Analyst Martin North looks at the bones of the scheme. What are the risks?

John’s Article: http://www.asgoodasgoldaus.com.au/blog/deposit-insurance-where-the-insurer-has-no-money-to-pay/

Yes, But What About Deposit Insurance? [Podcast]

Following on from our show on Deposit Bail-In, we discuss the Deposit Insurance arrangements in Australian and New Zealand.

What happens in a “gone” situation?

Digital Finance Analytics (DFA) Blog
Digital Finance Analytics (DFA) Blog
Yes, But What About Deposit Insurance? [Podcast]
Loading
/

Yes, But What About Deposit Insurance?

Following on from our show on Deposit Bail-In, we discuss the Deposit Insurance arrangements in Australian and New Zealand.

What happens in a “gone” situation?

https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2011/dec/pdf/bu-1211-5.pdf

https://www.fcs.gov.au/are-your-savings-protected

https://www.moneysmart.gov.au/managing-your-money/banking

https://treasury.govt.nz/publications/resource/questions-and-answers-phase-2-review-reserve-bank-act-second-round-consultation

NZ’s plan for deposit insurance falls well short of protecting people’s savings

From The Conversation.

The New Zealand government’s plan to introduce deposit insurance is a welcome step. Last week, finance minister Grant Robertson announced a new deposit protection regime to make the banking system safer for customers and to strengthen accountability for banks’ actions.

Worldwide, 143 countries have deposit insurance schemes, and New Zealand has long been an outlier. It is high time one was introduced.

How deposit insurance works

Currently, if a bank fails in New Zealand, depositors could lose all or some of their savings. Deposit insurance would change that and protect depositors’ savings. It operates like other types of insurance. If disaster strikes and a bank fails, depositors’ savings would be repaid up to a set limit.

According to Reserve Bank data, New Zealand households store about NZ$177.98 billion of their cash resources in banks. The proposed plan is important for all New Zealanders. Most people with a bank account are retail depositors and may be unaware of the vulnerable position they could find themselves in.

Under the Reserve Bank’s controversial open bank resolution policy, if a bank is distressed and under statutory management, part of a retail depositor’s savings may be frozen and used to recapitalise the bank, if shareholder and subordinated creditor funds prove insufficient. Essentially, New Zealand retail depositors would have to bail out their banks, unlike retail depositors in other countries who are protected by deposit insurance up to a set limit.

Apart from protecting depositors, the insurance helps to maintain stability in the financial system. It operates primarily to stop bank runs where depositors, afraid that they will lose their money, all demand repayment at once. Images of people lining up outside banks and at ATM machines all trying to get their money out were a feature of the 2007-2008 Global Financial Crisis (GFC). If people are confident that they will get their money back quickly from deposit insurance, they do not need to “run” on their banks.

Banks own the money you deposit

Depositors are vulnerable because once their money is with a bank, it no longer legally belongs to them. It belongs to the bank which can use it for its own commercial purposes. Typically, banks will lend this money to individuals and businesses (for example, through mortgages), making a profit by charging interest. In return, depositors get the right to repayment of their savings on demand.

Banks have fragile business models because they borrow short (through deposits which are repayable on demand) and lend long (through mortgages and other loans that are repayable at a fixed date in the future). Banks do not hold sufficient funds to repay all, or even most, of their depositors at once. Bank regulation provides some protection because banks are required to maintain certain levels of capital and liquidity, but if depositors panic and enough of them demand repayment, a bank can very quickly become insolvent.

Problems in one bank can pass to other banks and from banks to other types of businesses like a virus (this process is known as contagion). Eventually, this can build up to a financial crisis and lead to a recession, just as the GFC did in New Zealand and in many other countries. In a recession, almost everyone suffers, but the burden often falls most heavily on the poorest in society who have few assets to fall back on.

Protecting people and businesses

Retail depositors provide the bulk of bank funding in New Zealand (more than 60% of bank funding comes from households) and they currently carry a degree of risk of bank failure but are not properly protected by the law.

The Reserve Bank has traditionally opposed deposit insurance because of “moral hazard”. Their argument has been that protecting retail depositors from bank failure would discourage depositors from monitoring and disciplining their banks by withdrawing their savings if banks engage in overly risky activities.

This argument is based on the premise that retail depositors are capable of monitoring their banks, which requires a high level of financial literacy. The weakness in this argument was exposed during the GFC when New Zealand was forced to establish a temporary deposit guarantee scheme to reassure depositors that their savings were safe. Other countries, like the UK, recognise this vulnerability and provide an appropriate level of deposit insurance.

The New Zealand government has proposed a limit of between NZ$30,000 and NZ$50,000, saying that this would cover up to 90% of depositors. But this is well below the limits set by other comparable countries. For example, the limit is about NZ$374,000 in the US, NZ$114,000 in Canada, NZ$161,000 in the UK and NZ$262,000 in Australia.

If the limit is too low, the risk is that the deposit insurance scheme will not stop bank runs and not protect financial stability and the economy. It could even cause pre-emptive bank runs. If that happened, the government would need to urgently increase the deposit insurance limit and take other extraordinary measures, but this can lead to other difficulties, including increased overall costs, which ultimately fall back on the taxpayer.

Defining the best limit

One rule of thumb says the limit should be two to three times a country’s per-capita GDP. For New Zealand, this would mean between NZ$100,000 and NZ$150,000.

The government should be given credit for raising the issue of deposit insurance – a scheme should have been introduced years ago. But the low limit was proposed without public consultation. That is wrong.

The deposit insurance limit should not be decided solely by the Reserve Bank and Treasury. Other stakeholders have an important and valuable contribution to make. The debate should be transparent and well informed.

The second phase of the current review of the Reserve Bank Act will look at how a deposit insurance scheme should be funded. It should also include public consultation on the optimal level of deposit insurance. Having finally got the issue on the table, we should not squander the opportunity to do something important for New Zealanders.

Author: Helen Mary Dervan, Senior lecturer in law BCL(Oxon), TEP, Auckland University of Technology

NZ Reserve Bank Says Deposit Insurance To Happen

In the Phase 2 document released today, Deposit Insurance, funded by a bank levy is proposed. Unlike the Australian $250k scheme (which is not activated until the Government says so, and is taxpayer funded initially), the NZ scheme is for a lower amount with a protection limit in the range of $30,000 – $50,000. Implementation will probably take at least two years.

One question so far not answered is the interaction with the deposit bail-in. Generally bail-in stops a failing bank from failing, whereas deposit guarantees are activated on failure. So bail-in might stop deposit guarantees even being called on…

Depositor Protection

Why is a range of $30,000 – $50,000 for the proposed depositor protection scheme proposed?

Available data suggests that a protection limit in the range of $30,000 – $50,000 could fully protect from loss more than 90 percent of individual bank depositors in New Zealand, while leaving the majority of banks’ deposit funding exposed to risk. This would strike the right balance between protecting small depositors from loss and enhancing public confidence in the banking system on the one hand, while maintaining private incentives to monitor bank risk taking on the other. It would also be broadly consistent with international schemes in terms of the share of deposits and depositors that would be fully protected (albeit relatively low in terms of the absolute dollar value of protections).

More work will be required to choose the limit within this range that is the best for advancing the public policy objectives chosen for the protection scheme. The consultation seeks feedback on these choices.

The Reserve Bank is proposing high capital requirements for banks which should reduce the risk of bank failure. Why is depositor protection required if the risk of bank failure is small?

Even with high capital requirements, banks can still fail for a variety of reasons. Regulation, supervision, resolution, and deposit protection all make up a ‘financial safety net’ that supports a stable and resilient financial system and protects society from the damage caused by bank failures. The safety net tools interact and overlap, which can make it seem that not all of the tools are necessary. However, if the safety net is incomplete, it will be difficult to find effective solutions for dealing with serious problems in the banking system. This means that capital tools that help to keep banks safe and sound at the ‘top of the cliff’, must be complemented by robust tools to deal with banks that may still fall to the bottom.

The OECD and IMF have warned that, without depositor protection, New Zealand is vulnerable to contagious bank runs. Bank runs can escalate into banking crises that destroy social and financial capital. For New Zealand’s safety net to be effective in good times and bad, the tools within the net must each be strong in its own right, and work well together.

How will the risks associated with moral hazard be addressed in the proposed depositor protection scheme?

Moral hazard arises when people are protected from the consequences of their risky behaviour. If deposit protection is introduced, depositors may take less care when assessing the risks associated with their banks, and banks may take less care with depositors’ money. Moral hazard costs are part of the reason why New Zealand has until now chosen not to have a depositor protection regime.

There is considerable international experience on how to design an effective deposit protection scheme, within the broader financial safety net, that mitigates moral hazard. International experience demonstrates that strong regulatory monitoring of deposit-takers’ corporate governance and risk management systems goes a long way to addressing the moral hazard of depositor protection.  Maintaining private monitoring incentives is also important, and can be achieved through carefully calibrating the protection scheme’s scope of coverage. For example, setting the protection limit at a level that fully covers most household and small business depositors, but leaves large institutional depositors exposed to risk, will support private monitoring incentives. In conjunction, having effective resolution tools (that make it more credible investors’ money is at risk should their institution fail) can sharpen monitoring by institutional investors.

International practice and guidance, as well as the views of experts and the public, will inform the design of New Zealand’s depositor protection scheme.  

What are the costs of funding the proposed depositor protection scheme and who will bear these costs?

A primary tool of the protection scheme will be insurance. Deposit insurance transfers the risks and costs of bank failures away from depositors onto an insurance scheme. This will come with upfront costs of establishing a deposit insurer, and ongoing operational costs.

Modern deposit insurance schemes are normally funded by levies on member banks, supported (where necessary) by temporary lending paid for by taxpayers. If the insurance scheme is accompanied by a depositor preference, this might also increase banks’ non-deposit funding costs as risks are transferred from depositors onto institutional investors.

Details of the scheme, including costs, are still to be worked out in the next phase of the work programme. To the extent that depositor protection increases banks’ average costs, this might be passed on to customers through higher mortgage rates or lower deposit rates. Alternatively, costs might be absorbed by banks’ own margins and retained earnings. The extent to which costs are shared between banks and their customers depends on competition and contestability in the sector.

A fuller cost-benefit analysis will follow as we learn more about the specific design features of New Zealand’s depositor protection scheme.

When will the depositor protection scheme be introduced?

A work programme running alongside the Reserve Bank Review process will develop a depositor protection scheme that is best for New Zealand. The work programme will be guided by a framework setting out some key design principles for an effective scheme, and will draw (where relevant) on international standards and best practice. The work programme will determine the:

  • mandates and powers
  • governance and decision making structure
  • coordination arrangements with other safety net providers
  • membership and coverage arrangements
  • funding and pay-out mechanics, and
  • design features to mitigate moral hazard 

that are appropriate for New Zealand’s protection scheme. The Review Team’s discussions with the global coordinating body for deposit insurers indicates that the path from policy recommendations to scheme implementation will probably take at least two years.

Increased funding of European deposit guarantee schemes announced

On 17 June, the European Banking Authority (EBA), published 2018 data on national Deposit Guarantee Schemes (DGSs) across the European Economic Area (EEA), which show that 32 of 43 DGSs increased their funds available to cover deposits in 2018 by levying banks.

Here of course the $250k deposit scheme is unfunded and currently inactive.

Moody’s says that the target of 0.8% of covered deposits by 2024 set out in the Deposit Guarantee Schemes Directive (DGSD) has already been achieved in 17 of the 43 DGSs in the EEA. The gradually increasing harmonisation of DGSs in Europe is credit positive for European banks because it improves European banking systems’ financial stability by better protecting depositors against the consequences of credit institution insolvency. As DGS funding increases and exceeds the 0.8% threshold, they also expect banks’ levies to moderate, which will benefit their profitability.

Since the 2009 financial crisis, European authorities developed policies and tools to buttress financial systems’ resiliency and help authorities prevent and, if needed, tackle bank distress without having to resort to taxpayers’ support. DGSs form one of these tools.

Under current EU legislation, depositors are protected by their national DGS up to €100,000 (or the equivalent in local currency). This protection applies regardless of whether ex ante funding has been accrued by DGS. Under the DGSD, all EEA banks are required to contribute to national DGSs so that at least 0.8% of covered deposits are funded by 2024 (and by exception, no less than 0.5% of the covered deposits, like in France2).

Nine member states have set up DGSs with higher funding targets such as Romania (3.43%) and Poland (2.6%). Some countries, such as Iceland, have not yet defined their national funding target, while others have defined numerous DGSs for different categories of banks and depositors, as in Germany for private, public, savings or cooperative banks, hence there are more DGS than there are EU countries.

As of year-end 2018, 16 countries had already reached the DGSD’s 0.8% minimum funding ratio for 2024, and 10 countries exceeded their national target. The levies banks paid increased by around 12% in 2018, while covered deposits grew only by 3.6%. As of year-end 2018, EEA member states had reached in aggregate a funding ratio of 0.65% of covered deposits, up from 0.6% in 2017.

Out of the 31 banking systems addressed in the EBA report, 25 increased the funding for the DGSs in 2018, with very large increases in Ireland (+105.2%), Slovenia (+59.2%) or Luxembourg (+57.3%). The diversity in funding efforts reflects different starting points since some countries did not have DGS or limited ex-ante funding when the DGSD was adopted. For instance Luxembourg had no funding in 2015 and a target of 1.6% of covered deposits.

Despite progress, the third pillar of the banking union – the European deposit insurance scheme (EDIS) proposal adopted in 2015 – is not yet in sight due to a lack of political consensus. The EDIS proposal builds on the system of national DGSs and would provide a stronger and more uniform degree of insurance cover in the euro area. This framework would reduce the vulnerability of national DGSs to large local shocks.