The Reserve Bank will consider quantitative easing once rates fall to 25 basis points. It’s a tool that has been used by other countries, often with devastating consequences for society. Via InvestorDaily.
Australia
is in uncharted territory, economically speaking. We’re latecomers to
the low-rate party and we’re still getting used to it. Home owners are
loving it but retailers are not. Unemployment is low but a record number
of Aussies want to work more. It’s a strange time.
The Reserve
Bank of Australia only has a few options left if it fails to hit its
inflation target and lift economic growth. It can continue to reduce the
cash rate and even go into negative rates, as the European Central Bank
(ECB) had done. The ECB benchmark deposit rate was cut by 10 basis
points in September to negative 0.5 per cent. The ECB also reintroduced
its quantitative easing program of buying 20 billion euros ($32 billion)
worth of government and corporate bonds every month in an effort to
prevent the European economy from sliding off a cliff.
The ECB
has been using QE on and off since 2009 in an effort to lift inflation.
In 2015 the central bank began purchasing 60 billion euros worth of
bonds each month. This increased to 80 billion euros in April 2016
before coming back down to 60 billion a year later.
In the UK,
the Bank of England bought gilts (British government bonds) and
corporate bonds during its QE program during the global financial crisis
in 2009. QE programs also took place in 2011 and 2016.
Meanwhile,
the US Federal Reserve has undertaken three separate rounds of QE, the
last of which it began tapering in June 2013. The US halted its program
in October 2014 after acquiring a total US$4.5 trillion of assets.
When
a QE program takes place, a central bank begins buying securities with
money that didn’t exist before the QE process began. They are
essentially printing money and giving it to large corporates and the
government through the purchase of these bonds, the logic being that the
proceeds will be used to buy new assets (like mortgages) and invest,
which in turn will drive the economy.
The money doesn’t directly
hit the wallets of consumers. Unlike “helicopter money”, which the Rudd
government dished out during the financial crisis, QE has a much more
indirect impact on consumers. Financially speaking.
But the broader political and social impacts have had a lasting psychological effect on the populations of Europe and the US.
“If
we look at the experience offshore, QE has been great at raising the
level of assets in conjunction with a permanently lower interest rate,”
Fidelity International’s Anthony Doyle said this week.
“QE has
stimulated asset price growth. The ‘haves’ have benefited compared to
the ‘have nots’; income inequality has grown across the economies that
have implemented quantitative easing and socially we have seen big
shifts to the Right or to the Left in terms of the political spectrum.
“If
you think about Donald Trump, Elizabeth Warren, Bernie Sanders, Jeremy
Corbyn, Brexit, Boris Johnson. The next decade could be characterised by
moves to the Right or Left here as well if we follow a path that other
economies have pursued.”
AMP Capital chief economist Shane Oliver
told Investor Daily that QE “probably helps people who have shares and
property more than it does people who have bank deposits.”
Prior
to the election of Mr Trump in 2016, Luis Zingales of the University of
Chicago Booth School of Business told Bloomberg that central bank
policies are largely to blame for the rise of populism.
Here in
Australia, the Reserve Bank will have to consider the impact that QE
could have on a society that has witnessed a banking royal commission
that exposed widespread misconduct within the financial services
industry.
If the impact on Europe and the US of QE on the people
is anything to go by, Australia is well placed to split down the middle
and begin gathering on the far edges of the political spectrum.
We were late to the low rate party. We might just be late to the populism party too.
As expected the RBA held the cash rate today, but still leaves the door open for cuts next year. Given the weaker economic data we are seeing, those further cuts are pretty much assured.
At its meeting today, the Board decided to leave the cash rate unchanged at 0.75 per cent.
The outlook for the global economy remains reasonable. While the risks are still tilted to the
downside, some of these risks have lessened recently. The US–China trade and technology disputes
continue to affect international trade flows and investment as businesses scale back spending plans
because of the uncertainty. At the same time, in most advanced economies unemployment rates are low and
wages growth has picked up, although inflation remains low. In China, the authorities have taken steps
to support the economy while continuing to address risks in the financial system.
Interest rates are very low around the world and a number of central banks have eased monetary policy
over recent months in response to the downside risks and subdued inflation. Expectations of further
monetary easing have generally been scaled back. Financial market sentiment has continued to improve and
long-term government bond yields are around record lows in many countries, including Australia.
Borrowing rates for both businesses and households are at historically low levels. The Australian dollar
is at the lower end of its range over recent times.
After a soft patch in the second half of last year, the Australian economy appears to have reached a
gentle turning point. The central scenario is for growth to pick up gradually to around
3 per cent in 2021. The low level of interest rates, recent tax cuts, ongoing spending on
infrastructure, the upswing in housing prices and a brighter outlook for the resources sector should all
support growth. The main domestic uncertainty continues to be the outlook for consumption, with the
sustained period of only modest increases in household disposable income continuing to weigh on consumer
spending. Other sources of uncertainty include the effects of the drought and the evolution of the
housing construction cycle.
The unemployment rate has been steady at around 5¼ per cent over recent months. It is
expected to remain around this level for some time, before gradually declining to a little below
5 per cent in 2021. Wages growth is subdued and is expected to remain at around its current
rate for some time yet. A further gradual lift in wages growth would be a welcome development and is
needed for inflation to be sustainably within the 2–3 per cent target range. Taken
together, recent outcomes suggest that the Australian economy can sustain lower rates of unemployment
and underemployment.
Inflation is expected to pick up, but to do so only gradually. In both headline and underlying terms,
inflation is expected to be close to 2 per cent in 2020 and 2021.
There are further signs of a turnaround in established housing markets. This is especially so in Sydney
and Melbourne, but prices in some other markets have also increased recently. In contrast, new dwelling
activity is still declining and growth in housing credit remains low. Demand for credit by investors is
subdued and credit conditions, especially for small and medium-sized businesses, remain tight. Mortgage
rates are at record lows and there is strong competition for borrowers of high credit quality.
The easing of monetary policy this year is supporting employment and income growth in Australia and a
return of inflation to the medium-term target range. The lower cash rate has put downward pressure on
the exchange rate, which is supporting activity across a range of industries. It has also boosted asset
prices, which in time should lead to increased spending, including on residential construction. Lower
mortgage rates are also boosting aggregate household disposable income, which, in time, will boost
household spending.
Given these effects of lower interest rates and the long and variable lags in the transmission of monetary policy, the Board decided to hold the cash rate steady at this meeting while it continues to monitor developments, including in the labour market. The Board also agreed that due to both global and domestic factors, it was reasonable to expect that an extended period of low interest rates will be required in Australia to reach full employment and achieve the inflation target. The Board is prepared to ease monetary policy further if needed to support sustainable growth in the economy, full employment and the achievement of the inflation target over time.
According to an article in InvestorDaily, RBA Governor Philip Lowe has poured water on the prospects of quantitative easing (QE), saying Australia “shouldn’t forget about fiscal policy” to prevent a recession.
“QE is not on the agenda at this time,” Governor Lowe told at the annual dinner of the Australian Business Economists.
Interest
rates will have to hit 0.25 per cent before the RBA considers QE –
something that economists are predicting by mid-2020. But Governor Lowe
doesn’t think QE will be necessary, saying that the Australian economy
is in a good position and that the RBA will achieve its goals.
“At
the moment, though, we are expecting progress towards our goals over
the next couple of years and the cash rate is still above the level at
which we would consider buying government securities.”
However,
Governor Lowe hinted again that he would prefer the use of fiscal policy
rather than monetary policy to ward off a recession, citing a report
from the Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), which he
recently chaired.
“The
report also notes that there may be better solutions than monetary
policy to solving the problems of the day,” Governor Lowe said.
“It
reminds us that when there are problems on the supply-side of the
economy, the use of structural and fiscal policies will sometimes be the
better approach. We need to remember that monetary policy cannot drive
longer term growth, but that there are other arms of public policy than
can sustainably promote both investment and growth.”
Governor Lowe
also said that the willingness of central banks to provide liquidity
could reduce the incentive for financial institutions to hold their own
adequate buffers and create an “inaction bias” from prudential
regulators or fiscal authorities.
“If this were the case, it could lead to an over-reliance on monetary policy,” he said.
The
sentiments about quantitative easing have been echoed by fund managers.
Sarah Shaw, chief investment officer at 4D infrastructure and Chris
Bedingfield, principal at Quay Global Investors have urged the
government to instead allocate investment in infrastructure to create
jobs and boost productivity.
Ms Shaw noted the need to replace
roads, bridges and other structures with better planned
“forward-thinking” infrastructure is high.
“If you think about the
need for infrastructure spend that I’m talking about, if you put a
number on it, it’s maxed at $4 trillion by 2040 of infrastructure
capacity that’s needed,” she said.
“If you think about that and
you’re in an interest rate environment as low as it is today, if you’re
not borrowing to invest in a much-needed infrastructure, then there’s
something wrong.”
She added she looks for companies that are
locking in fixed term bet to invest for future cash flows, because “now
is the time to do it” with the current low cash rate.
“Why shouldn’t countries be doing that?” Ms Shaw queried.
“I’ll
give you an example: China during the GFC, biggest form of quantitative
easing – 35,000 kilometres of high-speed rail. That’s the sort of
quantitative easing that we should be looking at here in Australia.”
VanEck has predicted there will be more rate cuts in 2020.
As discussed with John Adams in our recent post, we did not come away with the same conclusion, and Westpac, for example is forecasting QE will hit during 2020.
Last night, in a much anticipated speech broadcast live on the Reserve Bank’s website, Governor Phil Lowe laid out in very clear terms the circumstances in which the bank would resort to quantitative easing and the way in which it would implement it. Via The Conversation.
Quantitative easing is simply a change in the way it eases monetary policy when the official interest rate approaches zero.
Usually it does it by cutting the so-called cash rate, which is the rate banks pay each other for money deposited overnight.
Eight years ago the cash rate was 4.5%. Three years ago it was 1.5%.
After the most recent three cuts in June, July and October, it is just
0.75%
Last night, Governor Lowe said the effective lower bound was 0.25%.
Rather than let the cash rate get any lower or negative (an option he
explicitly ruled out), the bank will push down other longer-term rates
by buying government bonds.
It’s the “quantitative easing” approach adopted by the US Federal Reserve between 2009 and 2014.
Government bonds are sold by governments in return for money, a means
of borrowing. The buyer gets guaranteed interest payments and a
guarantee that their money will be returned in full after three, five,
ten or even 20 years depending on the length of the bond.
Once issued, bonds can be traded on a market, and the price at which
they change hands can be expressed as an implied interest rate, which
becomes the risk-free rate against which all other interest rates are
benchmarked.
How quantitative easing would work
Buying bonds from investors would push down that risk-free rate, pushing down the entire structure of long-term interest rates.
All other things being equal, this should also push down the exchange
rate by reducing the return on Australian dollar denominated financial
investments.
Governor Lowe indicated he might buy state government bonds as well as Commonwealth bonds.
Importantly, he argued that although the bank would be mindful of the
need to ensure private banks had enough access to the bonds they needed
to hold for regulatory purposes, those holdings would not be an
impediment to quantitative easing.
He ruled out buying residential mortgage-backed securities and other
private assets given that those markets are currently functioning well
and Reserve Bank purchases could distort them.
The approach borrows heavily from the US Fed.
As in the US, Lowe says quantitative easing would be complemented by
“forward guidance,” where the Reserve Bank would signal early how
long-term interest rates would be kept low and the circumstances in
which it expected to raise them again.
The guidance is designed to influence market expectations for future
interest rates, enhancing the effectiveness of cuts in long term
interest rates.
When it would happen
In addition to “how,” Governor Lowe spelled out “when” – the economic
circumstances in which the bank would resort to quantitative easing.
It would do it when the cash rate was at 0.25% and inflation and unemployment were moving away from its objectives.
The bank targets 2-3% inflation on average over time and has recently
identified 4.5% as the “full employment” unemployment rate.
Importantly, Lowe emphasised that the Australian economy has not yet
reached the point where a cash rate as low as 0.25% would be needed and
argued quantitative easing was unlikely to be needed in future.
The cash rate is at present 0.75%. Setting 0.25% as the effective
lower bound gives the Governor 0.5 percentage points left to cut before
implementing quantitative easing.
Implicitly, Governor Lowe is saying that those cuts of 0.5 percentage points will be enough to stabilise the economy.
A pause for a breath at 0.25%
Lowe also indicated the bank would not seamlessly transition to quantitative easing.
He implied there was an additional hurdle or threshold that would
need to be crossed, suggesting he would be reluctant to make the
transition.
His big problem is that neither inflation nor the unemployment rate are moving in the right direction.
The bank has undershot its inflation target since the end of 2014,
giving the economy a weak starting point going into an emerging global
downturn.
My research
on the US experience for the United States Studies Centre shows that
the main problem with is quantitative easing was that it was not done
soon enough or aggressively enough.
It might be better to be bold
While quantitative easing was effective, it could have been made more so had what was going to happen been made clearer.
The Fed went out of its way to limit the transmission of quantitative
easing to the rest of the economy, fearful it would be too potent and
lead to excessive inflation.
Those concerns proved misplaced. By pulling its punches, the Fed
ended up being less effective and having to pursue quantitative easing
for longer than if it had used it more aggressively.
Governor Lowe’s very obvious reluctance to go down the quantitative easing route suggests the Reserve Bank is in danger of making the same mistake, but it is not too late to learn from what happened in the US.
Author: Stephen Kirchner Program Director, Trade and Investment, United States Studies Centre, University of Sydney
Financial system vulnerabilities remain elevated and more effort is required to ensure that the system remains resilient over the longer-term, Reserve Bank Governor Adrian Orr says in releasing the November Financial Stability Report.
International risks to the
financial system have increased. Global growth has slowed amid continued
uncertainty about the outlook for world trade. This has resulted in reductions
in long-term interest rates to historic lows, including in New Zealand. While
necessary to maintain near-term inflation and employment objectives, prolonged
low interest rates can promote excess debt and investment risk-taking, and
overheat asset prices, Mr Orr says.
Mr Orr noted that the Reserve Bank’s Loan-to-Value Ratio (LVR) restrictions have been successful in reducing the more excessive household mortgage lending, thereby improving the resilience of banks to a significant deterioration in economic conditions.
But, there remains the risk that prolonged low interest rates could lead to a resurgence in higher-risk lending. As such, we have decided to leave the LVR restrictions at current levels at this point in time.
Mr Orr says the Reserve Bank
is committed to bolstering the long-term resilience of the financial system.
“Strong bank capital buffers are key to enabling banks to absorb losses and
continue operating when faced with unexpected developments. The Reserve Bank
has proposed increasing these buffers further with final decisions on the
Capital Review proposals to be announced on 5 December.”
Deputy Governor Geoff
Bascand says good governance and robust risk management processes within
financial institutions are important to maintain long term resilience. Our
recent reviews of banks and life insurers, and the number of recent breaches in
key regulatory requirements, reinforces the need for financial institutions to
improve their behaviour.
“We are engaging with
industry to ensure that they strengthen their own assurance processes and
controls. We have also reviewed our own supervisory strategy and will be taking
a more intensive approach, which will involve greater scrutiny of institutions’
compliance,” Mr Bascand says.
“Some life insurers have low
solvency buffers over minimum requirements. Recent falls in long-term interest
rates are putting further pressure on solvency ratios for some of these
insurers. Affected insurers are preparing plans to increase solvency ratios and
are subject to enhanced supervisory engagement. This highlights the need for
insurers to maintain strong buffers, and insurer solvency requirements will be
reviewed alongside an upcoming review of the Insurance (Prudential Supervision)
Act.”
Governor Philip Lowe spoke at the Australian Economists Dinner last night. In many ways, little new here, but the RBA thinks the zero bounds cash rate is 0.25%, and QE is an option, but only in a crisis. “There may come a point where QE could help promote our collective welfare, but we are not at that point and I don’t expect us to get there”.
He said: As I discussed in the Sir Leslie Melville lecture at the ANU a month ago, low interest rates are not a temporary phenomenon. Rather, they are likely to be with us for some time and are the result of some powerful global factors that are affecting interest rates everywhere.[1]
Given this assessment, it is not surprising that there is a lot of discussion internationally about the
use of so-called ‘unconventional’ monetary policies. People are rightly asking: if
interest rates are going to stay low and be constrained by a lower bound, what other monetary policy
options are there?
I have been part of these international discussions through chairing the Committee on the Global
Financial System (CGFS) at the Bank for International Settlements in Basel. Last month, the Committee
published a report titled: ‘Unconventional Monetary Policy Tools: a Cross-country
Analysis’.[2] The report reviews the experience with the use of unconventional policy tools and
discusses how these tools can be used by central banks to achieve their objectives. If you are
interested in these issues and have not looked at the report, I encourage you to do so.
This evening I would like to summarise some key observations of the report and then explore how those
observations might be applied to Australia.
The CGFS Report – the ‘Unconventional’ Policy Tools
The report discusses four unconventional policy tools.
The term ‘unconventional’ monetary policy has now become the conventional shorthand for a
wide range of policies, although I am not sure it is the best terminology. I say this because most of
these tools have always been in the toolkit of central banks and have been used in one way or another in
the past. What has been unconventional over recent times is the way these tools have been
used.
Negative interest rates
The first of the four tools discussed in the report is negative policy rates.
This is one tool that is truly unconventional.
Prior to the financial crisis, it was widely thought that zero was the lower bound for the policy
interest rate – so it was common to talk about the ‘ZLB’, or the zero lower bound.
It was thought that if interest rates went below zero, people would hold their savings in banknotes
rather than be charged by their bank to deposit their money.
But zero has not turned out to be the constraint that it was once thought to be. So we now talk about
the ELB – the effective lower bound – not the ZLB. While countries with negative interest
rates have seen some shift to banknotes, it has been on a limited scale only. This reflects the use of
bank deposits for making transactions and the fact that most banks in countries with negative interest
rates have set a floor of zero on retail deposit rates. These banks have judged that it doesn’t
make sense, either commercially or politically, to charge households and small businesses negative
interest rates on their deposits.
It is worth pointing out that negative policy interest rates have largely been a European phenomenon.
Policy interest rates have been negative in the euro area, Denmark, Sweden and Switzerland. Rates have
been lowest in Switzerland, at minus ¾ per cent (Graph 1). The only country outside
of Europe that has had negative policy interest rates is Japan, but even there it is only a very small
share of bank reserves at the Bank of Japan that earns a negative rate, at
minus 0.1 per cent.
Extended liquidity operations
The second unconventional policy discussed in the report is the extended use of central bank liquidity
operations.
In response to the financial crisis, many central banks made significant changes to their normal market
operations to deal with strains in financial markets that were impairing the supply of credit to the
economy.
While the specifics differ across countries, the changes to market operations included: expanding the
range of collateral accepted; providing much larger amounts of liquidity; extending the maturity of
liquidity operations; increasing the range of eligible counterparties; and providing funding to banks at
below the cost that was then prevailing in highly stressed markets, sometimes on the condition that the
banks provide credit to businesses and households.
This graph shows the size of the extended liquidity operations of the major central banks
(Graph 2). The biggest operations were during the crisis period of 2008 and 2009, with significant
liquidity support also being provided in 2011 and 2012 to support bank lending during the European
sovereign debt crisis.
It is worth recalling that during these periods of stress, banks had become very nervous about their
access to liquidity. This, in turn, made them nervous about lending to others, making the possibility of
a severe credit crunch very real. By providing financial institutions with greater confidence about
their own access to liquidity, central banks were able to support the supply of credit to the economy.
The CGFS report recognises that there were some side-effects of doing this, but the strong conclusion of
the report is that these measures eased liquidity strains in highly stressed bank funding markets and
helped restore monetary transmission channels to the broader economy.
Asset purchases – quantitative easing
The third policy tool discussed in the report is the outright purchase of assets from the private
sector, paying for those assets by creating central bank reserves – also known as quantitative
easing or QE.
These asset purchases were on an unprecedented scale and led to very large expansions of central bank
balance sheets (Graph 3). Before the financial crisis, the major central banks owned securities
equivalent to around 5 per cent of GDP. In recent years, this has risen to nearly
30 per cent. This is a very large change.
As part of their QE programs, central banks bought a wide range of assets, but the main asset purchased
was government securities. Central banks now hold nearly 30 per cent of government securities
on issue, which is equivalent to around 20 per cent of GDP. The largest purchases have been
made by the Bank of Japan, which holds almost 50 per cent of Japanese government bonds on
issue.
In the United States, the Federal Reserve also bought large quantities of agency securities backed by
the US government. Elsewhere, central banks bought private securities such as covered bank bonds,
corporate bonds and commercial paper. And the Bank of Japan bought equities via exchange traded funds
(ETFs) and real estate investment trusts.
The precise motivations for these asset purchase programs varied across countries, but a common
motivation was to lower risk-free interest rates out along the term spectrum, well beyond the short-term
policy rate. Buying government bonds was seen as reinforcing policy rate cuts and/or acting as a
substitute for further reductions in the policy rate once it was at its lower bound. The expectation was
that lower risk-free rates would flow through to most interest rates in the economy, boost asset prices
and push down the exchange rate.
A related motivation for buying government securities was to reinforce market expectations that policy
rates were going to stay low for a long time. This ‘signalling channel’ added to the
downward pressure on long-term bond yields.
Another motivation in some countries was addressing problems in specific markets. In the United States,
for example, the Federal Reserve purchased government-backed agency securities to support mortgage
markets. And the Bank of England purchased commercial paper to ease highly stressed conditions in
corporate credit markets.
Finally, the expansion of the central bank’s balance sheet through money creation should, in
theory, have stimulatory effects through the so-called ‘portfolio balance channel’. The
idea here is that as the central bank purchases securities with bank reserves, investors seek to
rebalance their portfolios, and in so doing push up other asset prices and lower risk premiums for
borrowers. It is difficult, though, to isolate this effect from the other channels I just spoke
about.
Forward guidance
The fourth policy response was forward guidance.
This took two forms: calendar based and state based. Under calendar-based guidance, the central bank
makes an explicit commitment not to increase interest rates until a certain point in time. Under
state-based guidance, the central bank says it will not increase rates until specific economic
conditions are met. We have seen examples of both in practice. Some central banks also have provided
forward guidance regarding their asset purchase programs.
A primary motivation of forward guidance is to reinforce the central bank’s commitment to low
interest rates. A related motivation is to provide greater clarity about the central bank’s
reaction function and strategy in unusual times. The experience has mainly been positive, with the
guidance helping to reduce uncertainty. There are, however, some examples where a change in guidance
caused market volatility. The ‘taper tantrum’ in the United States in 2013 is an example
of this.
Some Observations
Before I discuss the relevance of all this to Australia, I would like to make three broad observations,
drawing on the report as well as my own reading of the evidence.
The first is that there is strong evidence that the various liquidity support measures and targeted
interventions in stressed markets were successful in calming things down and supporting the
economy.
When markets broke down and became dysfunctional, the actions of central banks helped stabilise the
situation and helped avoid a damaging gridlock in the financial system. They also helped contain risk
premiums in highly stressed markets. It is also worth pointing out that many of the measures to support
liquidity were successfully unwound once the job was done – so they proved to be temporary,
rather than a permanent intervention.
The CGFS report also documents the positive effects of some of the other unconventional measures. In
general, though, I find this evidence less compelling. These various measures certainly pushed down
long-term yields and provided monetary stimulus in the depths of the crisis when it was needed. But
these extraordinary measures have continued way past the crisis period. In some countries, asset
purchases have yet to be unwound and it remains unclear when, and even if, this will happen. So a full
evaluation is not yet possible.
This brings me to my second general observation. And that is that there have been some side-effects of
the various unconventional measures. I will touch on a few of these that the CGFS report discusses.
The first is that the extensive use of unconventional monetary tools can change the incentives of
others in the system, perhaps in an unhelpful way.
It is possible that the willingness of a central bank to provide liquidity reduces the incentive for
financial institutions to hold their own adequate buffers, making episodes of stress more likely in the
future.[3]
It is also possible that the willingness of a central bank to use its full range of policy instruments
might create an inaction bias by other policymakers, either the prudential regulators or the fiscal
authorities. If this were the case, it could lead to an over-reliance on monetary policy.
A second side-effect is the impact on bank lending and the efficient allocation of resources.
Persistently low or negative interest rates and a flattening of the yield curve can damage bank
profitability, leading to less capacity to lend. In some countries, there are concerns that low interest
rates allow less-productive (zombie) firms to survive. There are also financial stability risks that can
come from low interest rates boosting asset prices (and perhaps borrowing) at a time of weak economic
growth.
A third side-effect is a possible blurring of the lines between monetary and fiscal policy. If the
central bank is buying large amounts of government debt at zero interest rates, this could be seen as
money-financed government spending. In some circumstances, this could damage the credibility of a
country’s institutional arrangements and create political tensions. Political tensions can also
arise if the central bank’s asset purchases are seen to disproportionality benefit banks and
wealthy people, at the expense of the person in the street. This perception has arisen in some countries
despite the strong evidence that the various monetary measures supported both jobs and income growth and
thereby helped the entire community.
These are all side-effects we need to take seriously.
The third general observation is that experience suggests that a package of measures works best, with
clear communication that enhances credibility. Exactly what that package looks like varies from country
to country and depends upon the specific circumstances. But clear communication from the central bank
about its objectives and its approach is always important.
The report also notes that there may be better solutions than monetary policy to solving the problems
of the day. It reminds us that when there are problems on the supply-side of the economy, the use of
structural and fiscal policies will sometimes be the better approach. We need to remember that monetary
policy cannot drive longer-term growth, but that there are other arms of public policy than can
sustainably promote both investment and growth.
Application to Australia
I would now like to turn to what this all implies for us in Australia.
I will make five sets of observations.
The first is that the Reserve Bank has long had flexible market operations that allow us to ensure
adequate liquidity in Australian financial markets. We have used this flexibility in the past,
particularly during the global financial crisis, and we are prepared to use it again in periods of
stress if necessary.[4]
At the moment, though, Australia’s financial markets are operating normally and our financial
institutions are able to access funding on reasonable terms. In any given currency, the Australian banks
can raise funds at the same price as other similarly rated financial institutions around the world, and
markets are not stressed. So there is no need to change our normal market operations to do anything
unconventional here. Having said that, if markets were to become dysfunctional, you can be reassured by
the fact that we have both the capacity and willingness to respond. But this is not the situation we are
currently in. Things are operating normally.
The second observation is that negative interest rates in Australia are extraordinarily unlikely.
We are not in the same situation that has been faced in Europe and Japan. Our growth prospects are
stronger, our banking system is in much better shape, our demographic profile is better and we have not
had a period of deflation. So we are in a much stronger position.
More broadly, though, having examined the international evidence, it is not clear that the experience
with negative interest rates has been a success. While negative rates have put downward pressure on
exchange rates and long-term bond yields, they have come with other effects too. It has become
increasingly apparent that negative rates create strains in parts of the banking system that can impair
the ability of some banks to provide credit. Negative interest rates also create problems for pension
funds that need to fund long-term liabilities. In addition, there is evidence that they can encourage
households to save more and spend less, especially when people are concerned about the possibility of
lower income in retirement. A move to negative interest rates can also damage confidence in the general
economic outlook and make people more cautious.
Given these considerations, it is not surprising that some analysts now talk about the ‘reversal
interest rate’ – that is, the interest rate at which lower rates become contractionary,
rather than expansionary.[5] While we take the possibility of a reversal rate seriously, I am confident that
here, in Australia, we are still a fair way from it. Conventional monetary policy is still working in
Australia and we see the evidence of this in the exchange rate, in asset prices and in the boost to
aggregate household disposable income.
My third observation is that we have no appetite to undertake outright purchases of private sector
assets as part of a QE program.
There are two reasons for this. The first is that there is no sign of dysfunction in our capital
markets that would warrant the Reserve Bank stepping in. The second is that the purchase of private
assets by the central bank, financed through money creation, represents a significant intervention by a
public sector entity into private markets. It comes with a whole range of complicated governance issues
and would insert the Reserve Bank very directly into decisions about resource allocation in the economy.
While there are some scenarios where such intervention might be considered, those scenarios are not on
our radar screen.
My fourth point is that if – and it is important to emphasise the word
if – the Reserve Bank were to undertake a program of quantitative easing, we would
purchase government bonds, and we would do so in the secondary market. An important advantage in buying
government bonds over other assets is that the risk-free interest rate affects all asset prices and
interest rates in the economy. So it gets into all the corners of the financial system, unlike
interventions in just one specific private asset market.
If we were to move in this direction, it would be with the intention of lowering risk-free interest
rates along the yield curve. As with the international experience, this would work through two channels.
The first is the direct price impact of buying government bonds, which lowers their yields. And the
second is through market expectations or a signalling effect, with the bond purchases reinforcing the
credibility of the Reserve Bank’s commitment to keep the cash rate low for an extended period.
Currently, the government bond yield curve sits around 20 basis points above the overnight indexed
swaps (OIS) curve, which represents the market’s average expectation of the future monetary policy
rate (Graph 4). Purchasing government securities could compress this differential and could also
flatten the OIS curve through the expectations effect I just mentioned. A lower term premium would lower
borrowing costs for both governments and private borrowers, and would bring the benefits that come with
that. An exchange rate effect could also be expected.
Our current thinking is that QE becomes an option to be considered at a cash rate of
0.25 per cent, but not before that. At a cash rate of 0.25 per cent, the interest
rate paid on surplus balances at the Reserve Bank would already be at zero given the corridor system we
operate. So from that perspective, we would, at that point, be dealing with zero interest rates.[6]
My fifth, and final, point is that the threshold for undertaking QE in Australia has not been reached,
and I don’t expect it to be reached in the near future.
In my view, there is not a smooth continuum running from interest rate reductions to quantitative
easing. It is a bigger step to engage in money-financed asset purchases by the central bank than it is
to cut interest rates.
There are, however, circumstances where QE could help. The international experience is that in stressed
market conditions, the central bank can help stabilise the situation by buying government securities.
That experience also suggests that QE does put additional downward pressure on both interest rates and
the exchange rate. In considering the case for QE, we would need to balance these positive effects with
possible side-effects.
We would also need to consider the effects on market functioning. We are conscious that government
securities play a crucial role as collateral in some of our financial markets. Given the limited supply
of government debt on issue, the Reserve Bank and APRA have already had to put in place special
liquidity arrangements for the banking system. We are also conscious that the Australian
government’s fiscal position means that the gross stock of government debt is projected to decline
relative to the size of the economy over the years ahead. These considerations are not impediments to
undertaking QE, but we would need to take them into account.
It is a reasonable question to ask what might be the threshold to undertake QE in Australia.
It is difficult to be precise, but QE would be considered if there were an accumulation of evidence
that, over the medium term, we were unlikely to achieve our objectives. In particular, if we were moving
away from, rather than towards, our goals for both full employment and inflation, the purchase of
government securities would be on the agenda of the Board. In this world, I would hope other public
policy options were also on the country’s agenda.
At the moment, though, we are expecting progress towards our goals over the next couple of years and
the cash rate is still above the level at which we would consider buying government securities. So QE is
not on our agenda at this point in time.
It is important to remember that the economy is benefiting from the already low level of interest
rates, recent tax cuts, ongoing spending on infrastructure, the upswing in housing prices in some
markets and a brighter outlook for the resources sector. Given the significant reductions in interest
rates over the past six months and the long and variable lags, the Board has seen it as appropriate to
hold the cash rate steady as it assesses the growth momentum both here and elsewhere around the world.
The Board is also committed to maintaining interest rates at low levels until it is confident that
inflation is sustainably within the 2 to 3 per cent target range.
The central scenario for the Australian economy remains for economic growth to pick up from here, to
reach around 3 per cent in 2021. This pick-up in growth should see a reduction in the
unemployment rate and a lift in inflation. So we are expecting things to be moving in the right
direction, although only gradually.
The Board continues to discuss what role it can play in ensuring that this progress takes place and how
it might be accelerated. It recognises the benefits that would come from faster progress, but it also
recognises the limitations of monetary policy and the importance of keeping a medium-term perspective
squarely focused on maximising the economic welfare of the people of Australia. There may come a point
where QE could help promote our collective welfare, but we are not at that point and I don’t expect
us to get there.